The Competitiveness of Nations in a Global Knowledge-Based Economy
Eduardo Pol,
Peter Carroll and Paul Robertson
A New
Taxonomy of Economic Sectors with a view to Policy Implications
Content Abstract 1. Introduction 2. The Knowledge Based Economy and the Identification Problem 2.1 Knowledge-based Economy and New Growth Theory 2.2 Knowledge-based Sectors and High-technology Industries 3. A Taxonomy based on a Systems Approach to Innovation and Economic Growth 3.1 A Qualitative Matrix of Beneficial Flows 3.2 The Enabling/Recipient Taxonomy 4. Policy Implications 5. Summary and Concluding Remarks Appendix: Nomenclature Employed in this Paper Beneficial effects of Innovation |
Working Paper Series 2001 University of Wollongong Department of Economics
The authors are indebted to Ann Hodgkinson for helpful comments and suggestions. |
This paper is an attempt to tease out a taxonomy of
economic sectors based on a systems approach to innovation and economic growth
that may be useful for policy analysis. The taxonomy explored here revolves
around novel products rather than ethereal knowledge- producing entities. This insight goes back to Allyn Young
(1928) and Joseph Schumpeter (1934) who argued that the introduction of new
goods was the engine of economic growth. More precisely, our taxonomy of sectors
focuses on novel products which are efficiency-enhancing within and between
sectors through the market mechanism. The scheme revolves around the
relationship between ‘Enabling’ and ‘Recipient’ sectors (which gives the
taxonomy its name: ER), and offers a lens for viewing and interpreting a
substantive part of the mechanics of modern economic growth. The last part of the paper briefly
discusses a few immediate policy implications, although it has the potential for
greater use and value in this regard.
Key words: innovation, economic
growth, enabling linkages approach, knowledge-based economies, novel products,
efficiency-enhancing innovations
J.E.L. Classifications: L60, O38
Although all economic sectors 1 are to some
extent separated, most of them are also interrelated, and generally speaking,
the economy can be thought of as a system with interconnected parts. The idea that the economy is a system
with interconnected sectors goes back at least to Quesnay’s Tableau Economique (constructed by
Francois Quesnay in 1758) 2, and is
important as a conceptual basis for understanding of the process of economic
growth. Ideally, a systems approach
to innovation and economic growth would contemplate all of the linkages
(interactions and interdependencies in all directions) between the various
sectors of the economy. However,
taking into account all of the linkages is not feasible if we want to say
something more than ‘everything depends on everything’. A workable systems approach to innovation
and economic growth should recognize that as a rule every sector interacts with
every sector, but should also accept that in the real world some linkages
between sectors matter more than others because they enable the evolution of the
system as a whole. For lack of a
better term, we will call this methodological stance the key linkages approach to innovation and
economic growth or enabling linkages
principle.
Recent – and very influential, especially at the OECD
level - developments on the theoretical front are in line with the enabling
linkages principle. For example,
the model developed in Romer (1990b) revolves around the existence of a
“knowledge-producing sector” and its linkages with other sectors, and suggests
that the knowledge sector is strategically significant as an engine of enabling
technologies for other industries.
However, this latter approach faces the very difficult problem of
empirically identifying knowledge-producing sectors.
The literature concerning innovation-related
classifications of industries is surprisingly scant and tends to be dominated by
the Pavitt’s (1984) taxonomy and the OECD’s popular High-tech/Low-tech dichotomy
3. The use of Pavitt’s taxonomy is understandable because
his classificatory scheme has merit, but the use of the High-tech/Low-tech
dichotomy is unfortunate because it has only limited scope (Carroll et al
2000).
The present paper is an attempt to tease out a taxonomy
of economic sectors based on the enabling linkages principle. The taxonomy explored here focuses on
novel products rather than ethereal knowledge-producing entities. This insight goes back to Allyn Young
(1928) and Joseph Schumpeter (1934) who argued that the introduction of new
goods was the engine of economic growth. More precisely, our taxonomy of sectors
focuses on novel products which are efficiency-enhancing within and between
sectors through the market mechanism. Furthermore, our taxonomic scheme
revolves around the relationship between ‘Enabling’ and ‘Recipient’ sectors
(which gives the taxonomy its name: ER), and offers a lens for viewing and
interpreting a substantive part of the mechanics of modern economic growth.
As will become apparent, the
proposed ER taxonomy is independent of R&D intensities, innovation rates,
and the technological complexity of the products involved. In addition, the ER taxonomy circumvents
the awkward problem of identifying ‘knowledge -based’ sectors. Finally, we believe that the ER taxonomy
provides insight into the evaluation of the following innovation policy
principle: ‘enabling sectors and only enabling sectors should be the target of
government initiatives’. Our policy
interpretation of the ER taxonomy, based on the existence of complementarities between enabling and
recipient sectors, calls into question this principle.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section we consider the
notion of knowledge-based sector introduced by the OECD and the corresponding
identification problem. In
section
3 we define ‘Enabling’ and ‘Recipient’ sectors and put forward the ER taxonomy
of economic sectors. Section 4
briefly explores a few policy implications emerging from the ER taxonomy. Section 5 offers a summary and concluding
remarks. The paper also contains a
terminological appendix designed to facilitate interdisciplinary communication
between policy makers (many of whom come from the hard sciences and social
sciences excluding economics) and economists.
2. THE
KNOWLEDGE-BASED ECONOMY AND THE IDENTIFICATION PROBLEM
It is generally agreed that the systematic search for
profitable new ideas lies at the core of the knowledge-based economy. To quote a recent influential OECD
document at length,
OECD science, technology and industry policies should be
formulated to maximise performance and well-being in “knowledge-based economies”
– economies which are directly based on the production, distribution and use of
knowledge and information. This is
reflected in the trend in OECD economies towards growth in high-technology
investments, high-technology industries, more highly-skilled labour and
associated productivity gains. Although knowledge has long been an
important factor in economic growth, economists are now exploring ways to
incorporate more directly knowledge and technology in their theories and models.
“New growth theory” reflects the
attempt to understand the role of knowledge and technology in driving
productivity and economic growth.
In this view, investments in research and development, education and
training and new managerial work structures are key.
(OECD 1996, p.3, quotation marks in
original)
However, the definition of a knowledge -based economy
(henceforth KBE) as one which
is “directly based on the production, distribution and use of knowledge
and information” does not
help us to identify a KBE in the real world, as all industries depend to
some extent on the use of
knowledge.
2.1
Knowledge-based Economy and New Growth Theory
To gain further understanding of the meaning of a KBE a
rapid look at the theoretical base underlying the preceding OECD quotation is
useful. The unifying thread running
through New Growth Theory (NGT) is the view that technological change is
essentially an economic phenomenon, or at least explicable in economic terms
4. In fact,
technological change is considered as the result of intentional investments in
R&D and of R&D spillovers.
Furthermore, the mechanics of economic growth emphasized by NGT captures
the traditional idea of uneven growth: some sectors generate more economic
growth than others, for example through the creation of new
knowledge.
The basic NGT approach can be described as follows.
·
Technological change is
largely stimulated by the profit motive and comes from a knowledge-producing
sector which generates efficiency-enhancing ideas.
·
Ideas created by that
knowledge-producing sector are used by firms in the intermediate-goods sector,
which produces product outputs which may be consumed or invested.
·
The final-goods sector uses
labor, human capital, and the set of capital goods to produce final output.
·
An equilibrium gives the
paths for prices and quantities corresponding to a preassigned set of parameters
such as the stock of human capital and final output elasticities.
·
The free market mechanism
does not lead the economy to an optimum because knowledge will be generated
privately only if its dissemination is limited by (for example) patents thus
allowing those who generate knowledge to sell it for a positive price.
·
The existence of the
knowledge-producing sector is central to the NGT approach because it renders
increasing returns to scale in the economy as a whole inevitable. Intuitively, an increase in 1% in all
inputs results in an increase in output by more than 1% because, by definition,
nonrival inputs (somewhat roughly, profitable ideas) can be used over and over
again simultaneously by many people.
It should be stressed, again, that the foregoing
theoretical approach has a major empirical limitation concerning the
identification of the knowledge-producing sector. The first economist who made this point
forcibly was Nicholas Stern:
There are problems with this approach, however, if we
try to tell empirical stories. It
is extremely difficult to identify anything approximating to a knowledge
-producing sector in real economies. (Stern 1991, p.127)
To summarize, NGT emphasizes the importance of new ideas
in producing knowledge-driven growth, but the difficulty in making the insight
operational centers around the identification of the leading growth sector.
2.2
Knowledge-based Sectors and High-technology Industries
In the mid-1980s the OECD invented a classificatory
scheme based on R&D intensity: high-technology, medium-technology, and
low-technology industries. Table 1
shows the latest OECD classification. This table is reminiscent of the Tableau Economique in that it is a
primitive map of an extraordinarily vast and complex collection of facts. It is for this reason that we call Table
1 Tableau Technologique. The idea of classifying sectors on the
basis of their level of technology while interesting, is plagued with
difficulties (Carroll et. al 2000).
THE TABLEAU TECHNOLOGIQUE
(latest OECD classification of
industries by level of technology)
OTI
Direct R&D intensity
R&D/
R&D/
Production
value added
High tech
industries
Aircraft
17.30
14.98
36.25
Office and computing machinery
14.37
11.46
30.49
Pharmaceutical products
11.35
10.47
21.57
Radio, TV and comm. equip.
9.40
8.03
18.65
Medium-high tech industries
Professional goods
6.55
5.10
11.19
Motor vehicles
4.44
3.41
13.70
Electrical machinery
3.96
2.81
7.63
Chemicals
3.84
3.20
8.96
Other transport equipment
3.03
1.58
3.97
Non-electrical machinery
2.58
1.74
4.58
Medium-low tech industries
Rubber and plastic products
2.47
1.07
3.02
Shipbuilding and repairing
2.21
0.74
2.13
Other manufacturing
1.76
0.63
1.52
Non-ferrous metals
1.57
0.93
3.48
Non-metallic mineral products
1.44
0.93
2.20
Metal products
1.35
0.63
1.39
Petroleum products*
1.33
0.96
8.43
Iron and steel
1.10
0.64
2.48
Low tech industries
Paper and paper products
0.88
0.31
0.76
Textiles, apparel and leather
0.78
0.23
0.65
Food, beverages and tobacco
0.73
0.34
1.14
Wood products and furniture
0.65
0.18
0.47
* includes
refineries.
Legend: OTI =
Direct R&D intensity (measured by R&D/production) + Indirect R&D
intensity
Source: OECD
(1999), p.106
Note: The Tableau Technologique refers to the
year 1990.
The OECD’s dichotomy of high-tech/low-tech industries
has recently been applied with regard to the concept of KBE. As mentioned before, the notion of KBE
revolves around the tripod “use-production-distribution of knowledge”. The OECD (1999) has focused on the first
leg of this tripod and has not only adopted a working definition of
knowledge-based sectors based on the intensity of inputs of technology and human
capital but also has empirically identified the set of knowledge-based sectors.
The OECD defines knowledge-based
sectors as “those industries which are relatively intensive in their input of
technology and/or human capital”, and identifies the set of knowledge-based
sectors with High- technology industries, Communication services, Finance
insurance, real estate and business services, and Community, social and personal
services. (OECD, 1999, p.18)
Any identification of sectors, in this fashion, even if
offered as a suggestive rather than a substantive scheme must meet some minimum
requirements to ensure its validity. The distinction, for example, between the group of knowledge-based
sectors (for short, group A) and other types of sectors (nonknowledge-based
sectors or group B) has to be based on the assumption that we can study the
characteristics of group A most effectively if they are not merged with the
characteristics of group B. In
claiming that group A is distinct from group B, the OECD is saying that the
characteristics commonly found in A are so distinct from those in B that it is
methodologically improper to mix the two indiscriminately.
The essential distinguishing feature between a sector
belonging to group A, say ‘Office and computing machinery’, and another sector
contained in group B, for example, ‘Non-ferrous metals’, is, the OECD asserts,
the intensity of the use of knowledge characterizing the firms in each sector.
However, knowledge in this context,
is an ordinal (not cardinal) variable involving ‘more’ or ‘less’ knowledge, but
not how much. When we say, for
example, that ‘Radio, TV and communication equipment’ is a knowledge-based
sector and ‘Non-ferrous metals’ is not, we imply that the former uses more
knowledge that the latter. This
prompts the question: can we confidently say that Micron Technology (developing
a new generation of memory chips) or Microsoft (developing the “universal
canvas” technology 5)
are
using more knowledge than ALCOA (developing
the “inert anodes” technology
6) or Rio
Tinto (developing the “wettable cathodes” technology
7)? The basic answer is that we cannot. The data do not exist. But, what we do know is that according to
the OECD allocation of industries ALCOA and Rio Tinto are not included in the
group of knowledge-based sectors. This assertion is, to say the least,
debatable.
The line of division between groups A and B is blurred.
Given this fuzziness in delimiting
‘knowledge-based sectors’ from ‘nonknowledge-based sectors’ and in formulating
their distinctive characteristics, the identification problem remains unsolved.
Consequently, there is no solid
ground for using the OECD classification of knowledge-based sectors for policy
analysis.
As a first approximation, the problem of making a conceptual framework for policy analysis is a problem of consistent taxonomy of economic sectors guided by theoretical contributions and qualitative evidence derived from direct inspection of the growth process. The second approximation consists of a ‘reality check’, that is, the taxonomy should be quantifiable, so that the linkages underlying the scheme can be empirically tested. Hopefully, it should be useful in understanding patterns of activity in individual firms. Finally, the taxonomy should be simple enough for policy makers to visualize their role in the taxonomic system. In the next section, we offer the basis for what may be a useful taxonomy for policy makers in this area.
3. A TAXONOMY
BASED ON A SYSTEMS APPROACH TO INNOVATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH
The present section is conceptual, not empirical. We suggest an organizing tool to look at
the mechanics of economic growth, rather than trying to derive specific stories
from empirical data. It starts with
a pictorial description of the beneficial flows emerging from the innovation
process, and then reverts to the enabling linkages principle. Specifically, the aim here is to isolate
qualitatively a few stylized linkages between sectors in a way that is tractable
and suggests a new taxonomy of economic sectors.
3.1 A
Qualitative Matrix of Beneficial Flows
In general, the formulation of any analytical framework
is constrained by a trade-off between ‘tractability’ and ‘generality’, and the
present paper is not an exception to this general rule. Hence, because of the extreme difficulty
of directly observing actual knowledge spillovers, our focus is on the creation
and distribution of novel products (either new products or existing products
with new quality attributes) which are in turn producer goods
8. It is assumed that when the inputs
purchased by one sector from another (or from the same sector) embody efficiency
gains or quality improvements, the benefits are fully appropriated by the
selling sector.
Ideally, it would be desirable to construct an
economy-wide qualitative matrix in order to map the beneficial effects of novel
products. A pictorial description
of such a matrix of beneficial flows is given by
Table 2, where (a) sectors
originating novel products comprise the rows; (b) sectors (including end
consumers) using those novel products comprise the columns; and (c) the symbols
V and
X indicate the existence and non existence, respectively,
of beneficial effects 9. Considerable insight into the role of
the various sectors as growth-stimulating entities can be found by measuring the
magnitudes implicit in this qualitative matrix. However, the word ‘idealization’ in Table
2 reminds us that much of the required factual information does not exist at the
product level.
Qualitative Matrix of Beneficial Effects of Novel
Products
(Idealization)
Sector 1
Sector 2
…
Sector n
Consumers
Sector 1
V
V
…
X
V
Sector
2
X
V
…
V
V
.
.
.
Sector
n
X
X ...
X
V
Legend
V = Existence of beneficial
effects
X = Nonexistence of beneficial
effects
Even though the level of abstraction of the qualitative
matrix is very high, this visual model illuminates the separation between those
sectors sending beneficial flows through novel products and sectors receiving
those flows. A glance at Table 2
suggests the following starting point: there may be sectors able to enhance the
economy-wide ability to produce through the creation of novel products because
of their particular impact on other sectors.
3.2 The
Enabling/Recipient Taxonomy
Inevitably, terminology will play a crucial role in the
formulation of the taxonomy, so that we must begin with two definitions: (a) an
economic sector is termed enabling sector if the principal purpose of the
innovative endeavors of the firms operating in that particular sector is to
create novel efficiency-enhancing products for use as producer goods in other
sectors or eventually in the same sector; and (b) a sector buying novel
efficiency-enhancing products is termed a recipient sector. The distinction between enabling and
recipient sectors is not a mere terminological quibble. It will become apparent that it makes a
substantial difference for analysis and policy if firms are included in one
class of enabling sectors rather than another.
It follows from the preceding definitions that the very
existence of an enabling sector presupposes the existence of at least one
recipient sector. Or, to put it
differently, in correspondence with each enabling sector there will be one or
more recipient sectors. This
correspondence between sectors is established through a host of linkages between
enabling and recipient firms. It
should be noticed that the demand for novel products from the recipient sectors
is essentially a derived demand, that
is, demand for products not for their own sake but in order to use them in the
production of goods and services.
It should also be noticed that causation does not just
run one way, from enabling to recipient sectors. There are also feedback effects. For example, cost-reducing products may
be created on the basis of the insights provided by recipient sectors. These ideas are shown in
Fig.1.
It seems reasonable to base the ranking of enabling
sectors on the number of their associated recipient sectors because the larger
the number of receiving sectors the greater the impact of an enabling sector on
the growth performance of the economy as a whole. For example, electronics has an enabling
role in a large number of industries, including food processing, automotive
manufacturing, precision engineering and defence, medical and health services,
information technology, and telecommunications. By contrast, novel products originated in
the food processing industry, do not appear to have a magnifying effect on the
growth rate of other sectors. To
begin with, we formulate a crude separation into two polar classes:
• High-powered
enabling sectors (those that influence most of the recipient sectors); and
• Non-enabling
sectors (economic sectors whose novel products do not have perceptible
influence in the efficiency of other sectors).
High-powered enabling sectors (such as ‘Office and
computing machinery’) and non-enabling sectors (such as ‘Wood products and
furniture’) are at opposite extremes of the scale. But there is an area between these two
classes where the degree of impact of novel products on other sectors may be
more or less noticeable. We
describe them as ‘strongly’ and ‘weakly’ enabling sectors. Since it is difficult in practice to draw
a precise line as to where these two intermediate classes begin and end without
specific empirical research, the sector members of the two classes ‘Strongly
enabling sector’ and ‘Weakly enabling sectors’ should be considered only as
tentative.
Thus, our classification of manufacturing industry
consists of four classes:
• Class 1: High-powered Enabling Sectors;
• Class 2: Strongly Enabling Sectors;
• Class 3: Weakly Enabling Sectors; and
• Class 4: Non-enabling Sectors.
The enabling/recipient taxonomy (ER taxonomy for short)
emerges through the allocation of the manufacturing sectors mentioned in
Table 1
to these classes. The ER taxonomy
is presented in Table 3. Even
though each class of sectors contains variety, these categories appear to offer
a useful alternative scoping view on a rough-and-ready basis.
THE ENABLING/RECIPIENT
TAXONOMY
Economic
Sector
Enabling
Recipient
Class
1
Office and computing
machinery
VV
®
Radio, TV and comm.
equip.
VV
®
Professional goods
VV
®
Electrical
machinery
VV
®
Non-electrical machinery
VV
®
Class
2
Aircraft
V
®
Motor vehicles
V
®
Shipbuilding and
repairing
V
®
Chemicals
V
®
Pharmaceutical products
V
®
Other transportation
equipment
V
®
Class
3
Non-ferrous metals
(-)
®
Non-metallic mineral
products
(-)
®
Metal products
(-)
®
Iron and steel
(-)
®
Petroleum products
(-)
®
Other
manufacturing
(-)
®
Class 4
•
Rubber and plastic
products
(-)(-)
®
Paper and paper
products
(-)(-)
®
Food, beverages and
tobacco
(-)(-)
®
Textiles, apparel and
leather
(-)(-)
®
Wood products and
furniture
(-)(-)
®
Legend
VV high-powered enabling sector; V strongly enabling sector; ® recipient sector:
(-)
weakly enabling
sector; (-)(-)
non-enabling
sector
Given its high level of aggregation,
Table 3 has its
limitations. In particular, it is
necessary to carry out field studies in order to validate the groupings of
sectors presented in the Table. Similarly, the rank order within each
class of sectors cannot be established without detailed empirical research.
However, even at this level of
aggregation it has some value.
A comparison of
Tables 1 and
3, for example, shows that
there is no one-to-one correspondence between the High-tech/Low-tech
classification of industries given by the OECD’s Tableau Technologique and the ER
taxonomy of sectors. It is true
that there are sectors such as ‘Office and computing machinery’ or ‘Radio, TV
and communication equipment’ that are both High- tech and High-powered enabling
sectors, and similarly, we can find sectors that are both Low-tech and
Non-enabling, e.g. ‘Textiles, apparel and leather’ or ‘Woods products and
furniture’. But the correspondence
collapses for several sectors. For
example, ‘Aircraft’ and ‘Pharmaceutical products’ are High-tech, but not
High-powered enabling sectors.
The industries at the bottom- half of the OECD list
(Low-tech or ‘mature’ industries) have a long history and their technological
evolution mainly depends either on the creation of novel products in the
enabling sectors or on relatively low R&D effort within the industry. All these mature industries are included
in Class 3 or in Class 4 in Table 3.
The ER taxonomy is related to the classificatory scheme
developed by Pavitt (1984). Pavitt’s taxonomy proved a fruitful
framework for understanding patterns of industrial innovation through the
identification of supplier dominated firms, specialized equipment firms, scale
intensive firms and science based firms. The ER taxonomy, on the other hand, aims
at mapping sectoral links based on the creation and distribution of novel
products that allow producers to carry out their productive activities more
efficiently. As a result, the ER
taxonomy can be thought of as a complement to the Pavitt’s taxonomy, not a
substitute for it.
Before advancing to the policy consequences of the ER
taxonomy, three points should be emphasized. First, it is not the purpose of the
suggested taxonomy to capture the totality of the rich picture of the complex
interdependencies among industries underlying the process of technological
change, nor the intra and interindustry technological externalities. In particular,
Table 3 makes the tacit
assumption that the efficiency-enhancing effects emerging from the acquisition
of novel products work through the price mechanism, and therefore, can only
constitute pecuniary externalities. In other words, novel products are just
that, products, not technological externalities.
Second, the ER view highlights certain aspects of the
mechanics of innovation and economic growth and put others in the background.
It stresses the flows of efficiency
enhancing products, but the demand side of the growth process (e.g. income
elasticities of demand) and other macroeconomic parameters (such as company tax
rate, tariff rates, and tax concession rate) are obscured. The fact that such aspects are left out
of the picture does not imply that they are irrelevant, merely that they are not
the central focus of the taxonomy.
Finally, the ER taxonomy is based on stable
distinguishing features of the various economic sectors (the enabling role of a
sector does not appear to fluctuate significantly, except under technological
revolutions), and thereby, constitutes a departure from the standard dimensions
used to classify innovative industries such as R&D intensities, innovation
rates, and technological complexity of products. In addition, a corollary advantage stands
out, namely: the ER taxonomy does not depend on the identification of
knowledge-based sectors.
Conventional economic theory looks at the world through
the lens provided by the frictionless, perfectly competitive, constant returns
to scale paradigm, and implies what may be called the “equipollent postulate’,
namely: “all sectors are of equal value to the domestic economy.” It asserts, also, that government
support should be limited to providing a satisfactory economic environment, with
policy intervention justified only when free markets are subject to market
failure.
One of the fundamental tenets of NGT is that perfect
competition is logically inconsistent with economic growth. To be more precise, Romer (1990a) has
shown that under perfect competition it is impossible to remunerate nonrival
inputs, and therefore, the assumption of price-taking competition must be
abandoned. In this context, while
the NGT has provided a useful formal framework and a number of important
insights, it has not yet been very helpful on the question on how policy might
influence growth. As indicated in
section 2.1, NGT rejects the equipollent postulate and appears to suggest that
there is scope for government intervention beyond deregulation. The neo-Schumpeterian dimension of NGT
places innovation at the centre of long-run economic growth, and focuses
attention on R&D expenditure as a key policy variable.
Essentially, the NGT view is that a country’s economic
prosperity depends on its capacity for innovation, for which technological
innovation is a key driver in advanced countries. In rough outline,
R&D expenditure à increased knowledge and new products/processes
à economic growth.
In the context of NGT, R&D expenditure is both a
proxy for technological innovation and a black box . These implications, simple as they are,
seem to have played an important
role in guiding public technology policies in several OECD countries, for
they have focused on the stimulation of R&D expenditures. A variety of tax benefits, for example,
are provided in several countries in order to achieve the desired stimulation.
Apparently, some countries seem to have accepted the
‘black box’ without a full
understanding of its contents. There is uncertainty as to whether
R&D expenditures are a reliable
proxy for technological innovation, and importantly, as to the specific roles
played by R&D investment in relation to some mature industries. Faced with this uncertainty, what should
policy makers do? A range of
possibilities exist, including, but not restricted to the following four:
1.
Do nothing and let markets
rule, at least until and if economists provide more useful advice.
2.
Accept the neo-Schumpeterian
NGT argument and provide support for those sectors that engage in R&D, on
the assumption that R&D does drive innovation and, thus, economic growth.
As already indicated, the problem
here is that all sectors undertake some R&D and, similarly, are to some
extent knowledge-based, so that this ‘shotgun’ approach is likely to have
uncertain impacts. If all sectors
receive such support, this amounts to an endorsement of the equipollent
postulate.
3.
Accept the neo-Schumpeterian
NGT argument and encourage weakly enabling and non-enabling sectors to mimic the
innovation behavior of the firms in the other two classes by, for example,
increasing their R&D expenditure. Unfortunately, as Pavitt (1984) points
out, in some industries such as textiles and wood products, novelty has occurred
primarily on the basis of innovation undertaken in other sectors, rather than
having been ‘developed in- house’. Hence, would encouragement of innovation
in these sectors have any effect? Would it better directed to sectors that,
in our terminology, have ‘enabled’ innovation in textiles and woods products?
4.
As tends to be the case in
practice, constituting almost the conventional, OECD- inspired wisdom, restrict
support to the ‘High-tech’ industries that undertake high levels of R&D.
This would run foul of the
difficulties noted earlier.
We conclude this section by identifying where we think
the ER taxonomy provides insight into the current policy debate in OECD
countries, especially
One of the key features of the so called ‘new economy’
is the interaction between ‘old’ or ‘mature’ sectors performing bulk processing
of resources, such as foodstuffs, metal and ores, and relatively ‘new’ sectors,
e.g. office and computing machinery, yielding efficiency-enhancing products for
use in a variety of industries. In
other words, a ‘new economy’ consists of two interrelated worlds: a traditional
part (bulk processing of resources) and a newer part (creation of enabling
products). The two worlds are not
neatly split at the macro level, but it would be always possible to say whether
a particular company is mature or enabling. Table 3 is a telescopic view of these
interlaced worlds 10.
In the course of the shift from the ‘old economy’ to the
‘new economy’ policy makers have become obsessed with the magic incantation of
the enabling sectors. The rapid
growth of these sectors appears to revive the Say’s law of markets which can be
paraphrased as “the supply of efficiency-enhancing products across industries
creates its own demand” and underpin the current conventional wisdom, namely
‘enabling sectors and only enabling sectors should be the target of government
initiatives’.
The problem with this principle is that it overlooks the
simple, yet fundamental insight that there may be low growth were it not for the
activities of ‘new economy’ firms, but there would be no growth were it not for
‘old economy’ firms. We believe
that the policy message conveyed by the shift from the ‘old economy’ to the ‘new
economy’ has been deciphered incorrectly for at least two reasons. First, enabling and non-enabling sectors
are complementary rather than
substitutes. Human beings cannot
survive by eating ‘digital food’ or protect their health from cold weather by
wearing ‘virtual clothes’. Second,
the economic dynamics of the enabling sectors operating in countries where the
fundamentals for technological change are in place 11 suggests
that the ‘new economy’ firms will remain on the innovation treadmill
irrespective of additional
incentives.
Due to the existence of fierce competition, the firms
included in classes 1 and 2 will normally operate on their innovation
possibilities frontier, determined by the stock of human capital and the
endowment of physical capital. Therefore, it would be really difficult
to stimulate additional R&D expenditure through government incentives in
these classes. Undiscriminating
subsidies, for example, would give rewards for R&D investment that would
have happened anyway.
‘Create destructively or perish’ is the golden rule for
most new economy firms. In
contrast, creative destruction does not appear to be the predominant form of
non-price competition for firms operating in classes 3 and 4. The crucial role of these firms from the
point of view of aggregate growth is to defray a substantial proportion of the
fixed innovation costs incurred by firms operating in groups 1 and 2. Or, to put it differently, a substantial,
perhaps key part, of the demand for innovation that drives firms in groups 1 and
2 originates in groups 3 and 4, the mature sectors in an economy.
In essence, we believe that it is neither necessary nor
desirable to focus government incentives to economic growth only on classes 1 and 2. The firms operating in these sectors are
obliged by the forces of competition and increasing returns to scale to invest
in innovation to the maximum possible in order to survive. What these sectors basically need is a
world class endowment of human capital and science and technology institutions
addressing their needs. Government
support for the science base in universities and research institutes is
important for both classes (High-powered and strongly enabling sectors). In particular, government funding for
cooperative research (collaboration between enabling sectors, universities and
research institutes) to maintain (and attract) ‘new economy’ firms is not only
important but imperative.
The relative theoretic and policy neglect that mature
sectors have faced in recent decades, especially in countries that are dominated
by such sectors is evident. Our
view is that classes 3 and 4 (mature sectors) deserve more attention, or at
least attention comparable to that devoted to classes 1 and 2. For a small economy such as Australia’s,
the enhancement of the absortive capacity of mature sectors through technology
importation and dissemination may be just as important as R&D for domestic
enabling sectors.
It is a mistake to think that the newer part of the
economy will completely dislodge the traditional part of the economy. In the foreseeable future mature sectors
will occupy a sizable proportion of the economy because the existence of
enabling sectors presupposes the existence of recipient sectors. More precisely, a substantial part of the
market size for enabling sectors is given by the demand for innovation from
mature sectors. Hence, the end
result is that the level (and rate) of innovation of the ‘new economy’ companies
strongly depends on the performance of the ‘old economy’ firms.
5. SUMMARY
AND CONCLUDING REMARKS
People intuit that innovation in one enabling sector may
enlarge the size of the market for output in other sectors. For example, developing and integrating
satellite technology may allow new commercial and military applications, and
thereby, extend the market size of whole sectors that revolve around them. We have put forward a systematic way of
looking at economic sectors from the innovation-growth prism capturing this
intuition. What we have done is
qualitative and conceptual. Our
main objective has been to provide a clear conceptual framework for further
interpretation and quantitative work. To this end, we have used the enabling
linkages principle.
Economic sectors have been grouped in four classes on
the basis of their attributes to enhance the economy-wide ability to grow. In essence, Enabling sectors provide
novel products that are efficiency-enhancing across sectors, and Recipient
sectors are the beneficiaries of the corresponding pecuniary externalities.
The ER taxonomy is independent of
R&D intensities, innovation rates, and technological complexity of products,
and circumvents the awkward (and unresolved) problem of identifying
‘knowledge-based’ sectors.
The ER taxonomy involves logic, facts, and policy
implications, as in all economics. The logic is simple: new ideas
incorporated in efficiency-enhancing novel products lead to increasing returns
not only because the ideas can be used repeatedly and simultaneously by many
people, but also because these novel products generate cost-savings across
sectors. In a nutshell, increasing
returns are magnified by the enabling
role of some economic sectors. The
questions of fact are related to the ranking provided by
Table 3. Detailed empirical analysis will shed
light not only on the ranking within the classes but also on the reasonableness
of the allocation of sectors to the different groups.
To answer policy questions economists have to separate
what is relevant from what it is not in relation to the policy issue under
consideration. An important point
is the complementarity between enabling sectors and mature industries:
innovation in enabling sectors influences the size of the market for output in
mature sectors, but there is also a reverse influence in that the market size
for enabling sectors hinges on the demand for innovation from mature sectors.
One can view the ER taxonomy as arguing for the
importance of mature industries in the growth process because these industries
help defray the (fixed) innovation costs incurred by the enabling sectors. Specifically, our policy interpretation
of the ER taxonomy is that governments should put less emphasis on targeting
specific enabling sectors (classes 1 and 2) and concentrate more on enhancing
the absorptive capacity of the mature industries (classes 3 and 4). This interpretation reverses the
predominant conventional wisdom.
We plan to extend our qualitative approach in a number
of directions. First, we are aware
of the need of quantification of the enabling linkages principle underlying the
ER taxonomy 12. Our
second goal will be to explore in depth the role of government in coordinating
economic activity, particularly through market-friendly measures, in the light
of the ER taxonomy.