The Competitiveness of Nations
in a Global Knowledge-Based Economy
Harry Hillman Chartrand
April 2002
Organization for Economic Co-Operation and Development
THE
KNOWLEDGE-BASED ECONOMY
II. THE ROLE OF THE
SCIENCE SYSTEM IN THE
KNOWLEDGE-BASED
ECONOMY
A country's science system
takes on increased importance in a knowledge-based economy. Public research laboratories and
institutions of higher education are at the core of the science system, which
more broadly includes government science ministries and research councils,
certain enterprises and other private bodies, and supporting infrastructure.
In the knowledge-based economy, the
science system contributes to the key functions of: i) knowledge
production – developing and providing new knowledge; ii) knowledge
transmission – educating and developing human resources; and iii)
knowledge transfer – disseminating knowledge and providing inputs to
problem solving.
Despite their higher
profile in knowledge-based economies, science systems in OECD countries are now
in a period of transition. They are
confronting severe budget constraints combined with the increasing marginal
costs of scientific progress in certain disciplines. More importantly, the science system is
facing the challenge of reconciling its traditional functions with its newer
role as an integral part of a larger network and system – the knowledge-based
economy.
The science system has
traditionally been considered the primary producer of new knowledge, largely
through basic research at universities and government laboratories. This new knowledge is generally termed
“science” and has traditionally been distinguished from knowledge
generated by more applied or commercial research, which is closer to the market
and the “technology” end of the spectrum. In the knowledge-based economy, the
distinction between basic and applied research and between science and
technology has become somewhat blurred. There is debate as to the exact line
between science and technology and whether the science system is the only or
main producer of new knowledge. This debate is relevant because of
different views on the appropriate role of government in funding the production
of various types of knowledge.
Scientific knowledge
is broadly applicable across a wide and
rapidly expanding frontier of human endeavour. Technological knowledge stems more from
the refinement and application of scientific knowledge to practical problems.
Science has been considered that
part of knowledge which cannot or should not be appropriated by any single
member or group in society, but should be broadly disseminated. It is the fundamental knowledge base
which is generic to technological development. Because of this, much of science is
considered a “public good”, a good in which all who wish can and should
share if social welfare is to be maximised. The public-good character of science
means that, like other public goods such as environmental quality, the private
sector may under-invest in its creation since it is unable to appropriate and
profit adequately from its production.
The government therefore
has a role in ensuring and subsidising the creation of science to improve social
welfare, just as it does in regulating environmental
protection.
22
Some argue that there is no
longer a meaningful distinction between science and technology in the
knowledge-based economy (Gibbons et al., 1994). They present the view that the methods of
scientific investigation have been massified and diffused throughout society
through past investments in education and research. The consequence is that no particular, or
each and every, site of research investigation, public or private, can be
identified as a possible originating point for scientific knowledge. In addition, there may no longer be a
fundamental difference in the character of scientific and technological
knowledge, which can be produced as joint products of the same research
activity.
Studies of the research
process have demonstrated that incremental technological improvements often use
little scientific input and that the search for technological solutions can be a
productive source of both new scientific questions and answers. As a result, the traditional base of the
science system, research institutions and universities, cannot be assumed to
dominate the production of scientific knowledge.
In this view, firms in the
private sector will invest in basic research, despite its possible spillovers to
competitors, if they can capture enough value from the use or process of pursuit
of this knowledge in their other activities to justify investing in its
creation. This argument suggests a
major revision in the justification of public support for scientific research
and the need for policies to focus on the interaction among all the possible
sources of scientific knowledge. Public funding of research might be
needed to increase the variety of exploitable knowledge that might eventually
find its way into commercial application. For these scholars, the extent to which
scientific knowledge can be appropriated, directly or indirectly, makes it
necessary to modify or reject the idea that science is apublic
good.
In recent years, the
proportion of total research and development (R&D) financed by industry
has increased relative to the government share in almost all OECD countries.
Industry now funds almost 60
per cent of OECD R&D activities and carries out about 67 per cent of total
research (Table 4). At the
same time, however, overall growth in R&D spending is declining. In the OECD countries, growth in national
R&D spending has been on a downward trend since the late 1980s, and it fell
in absolute terms in the early 1990s. R&D expenditures have now levelled
off to account for about 2.3 per cent of GDP in the OECD area. Within this slowing R&D effort, it is
believed that spending on basic research may be suffering in some countries
(although not in the
There is also some
scepticism as to the ability of the private sector to conduct adequate amounts
of truly basic research. In
industry, basic research tends to be a search for new knowledge that may be
applicable to the needs of a company; it is not usually research driven simply
by curiosity or more general demands. It is also a small part of the overall
industrial R&D effort. In the
23
The science system is a
crucial element in knowledge transmission, particularly the education and
training of scientists and engineers. In the knowledge-based economy, learning
becomes extremely important in determining the fate of individuals, firms
and national economies. Human
capabilities for learning new skills and applying them are key to absorbing
and using new technologies. Properly-trained researchers and
technicians are essential for producing and applying both scientific and
technological knowledge. The
science system, especially universities, is central to educating and
training the research workforce for the knowledge-based
economy
Data show that the
production of new researchers in the OECD may be slowing along with lower
growth of R&D investments (Table 5). In the 1980s, there was substantial
growth in the number of researchers in the OECD area (defined as all those
employed directly in R&D in the public and private sectors), almost 40 per
cent in 1981-89 or the equivalent of 65 000 to 70 000 new researchers per year.
However, this was less rapid than
the 50 per cent growth in R&D expenditures in the same period. Both spending and human resource
development are proceeding at a slower pace in the 1990s. The growth in researchers in universities
and government research institutions has been slower than in the private sector,
which employs about 66 per cent of OECD research
personnel.
Regardless of their sector
of employment, these human resources are produced by the science system. Less research in universities,
laboratories and industry means fewer careers in science and insufficient
development of future scientists and engineers. In addition to lower research budgets,
universities are facing other difficulties. One problem is providing a broad-based
education to an increasing number of citizens while also directing
high-level training through research at the graduate and post-graduate levels.
In most OECD countries, there has
been a sharp increase in both the number of students and the proportion of young
people enrolled in higher education, leading to tensions between educational
quantity and quality.
24
Universities confront the
need to continue high-quality research and research training in the context of
diminishing resources and more overall student demands. At the same time, there
appears to be a divergence developing between marketplace needs for new
researchers and the qualifications and orientation of the supply of new
doctorates. There is a third problem of gaining the interest of young people in
careers in science, which could have serious implications not only for the
availability of researchers and engineers, but also for the awareness of the
general public with regard to the economic value of science and
technology.
The science system is thus
facing challenges in reconciling its knowledge production role, even more
important in the knowledge-based economy, and its knowledge transmission or
educational function. Many people believe that the primary mission of the
university is educational, reproducing and expanding the stock of individuals
that embody the accumulated knowledge and problem-solving skills needed in
modern societies. The fact that universities are, to varying degrees among the
OECD countries, also involved in the creation of new knowledge may be seen as a
by-product or joint product of their educational mission. In practice, the
educational mission of universities shapes their approach to conducting research
through the assignment of important research roles for students and their
participation in technical activities. As universities attempt to find ways
around fiscal limitations, there may be substantial variety in the extent to
which they maintain the primacy of their educational mission. Resource
constraints make it more difficult to maintain the necessary linkages and
balance between research and education.
The science system plays an
important role in transferring and disseminating knowledge throughout the
economy. One of the hallmarks of the knowledge-based economy is the recognition
that the diffusion of knowledge is just as significant as its creation,
leading to increased attention to “knowledge distribution networks” and
“national systems of innovation”. These are the agents and structures
which support the advance and use of knowledge in the economy and the linkages
between them. They are crucial to the capacity of a country to diffuse
innovations and to absorb and maximize the contribution of technology to
production processes and product development.
25
In this environment, the
science system has a major role in creating the enabling knowledge for
technological progress and for developing a common cultural basis for the
exchange of information.
Economies are characterised
by different degrees of “distribution power” in their ability to transfer
knowledge within and across networks of scientific researchers and research
institutions. The distribution power of an economy depends partly on the
incentives and existence of institutions, such as those of higher education, for
distributing knowledge. Effective distribution of knowledge, however, also
depends upon investing in the skills for finding and adapting knowledge for use,
and in developing bridging units or centres. There are thus choices to be made
between investments in the production of, and in the capabilities for diffusing
and using, scientific knowledge.
In the knowledge-based
economy, the science system must balance not only its roles of knowledge
production (research) and knowledge transmission (education and training) but
also the third function of transferring knowledge to economic and social actors,
especially enterprises, whose role is to exploit such knowledge. All OECD
countries are placing emphasis on developing linkages between the science system
and the private sector in order to speed knowledge diffusion. As a result,
incentives are being given by governments for universities and laboratories to
involve industrial partners in the selection and conduct of their research
activities.
In the case of higher
education, university/industry collaborations bring with them
opportunities to increase the relevance of the university's educational mission
and to stimulate new research directions. They provide a means both for the
efficient transfer of economically useful knowledge and for advanced training in
skills required by industry. Traditionally, much of the knowledge produced in
public facilities and universities has been prohibited from being patented by
the private individuals involved in creating it, and salaries and equipment have
been paid out of public funds. Now, joint research projects and other linkages
are calling heightened attention to economic issues such as exclusive licensing,
intellectual property rights, equity ownership, conflict of interest, length of
publication delays and commingling of funds.
There are other issues,
however, that may create a more profound effect on the contribution of
universities to science. Large amounts of industry research funding may induce
the participating universities to specialise their efforts in ways that will
prove detrimental over the long run to the range and character of research they
are able to conduct. An increasing share (as much as 50 per cent in some
universities) of the resources allocated to university research is derived from
contracts with industry, thus making the universities more and more dependent on
the private sector for funding and steering the overall research activity in a
more commercial direction. As university/industry collaboration becomes the norm
in many areas of basic research, the traditional contribution of academia to the
production of scientific knowledge may weaken under the burden of increasing its
economic relevance.
There are also concerns
that university/industry collaboration is tending to consolidate excellent
researchers in a handful of universities or research centres. Collaborative
efforts often require geographic proximity and a large base of expertise to
establish complementary infrastructure and to assure the transfer of relevant
knowledge. Such concentrations of research, whether organised as science parks
or simply arising from the concentration of existing industrial research
activities, may disadvantage smaller schools or centres. Moreover, concentration
of research efforts may constrain the ability of the excluded institutions to
offer students contact with high-quality research efforts. However, these
concerns may be unfounded in light of the increasing ability for researchers to
be linked electronically through information and communications
technologies.
26
The public or
governmental component of the science system is facing many of the same
questions. The structure of research councils is being modified to emphasise
strategic areas, to promote synergies between disciplines and to involve the
private sector. Industry is being asked to help define the areas in which
research, including basic research, should be done. Government laboratories are
forming joint ventures with the private sector. In the knowledge-based economy,
governments are earmarking more funds for science activities considered to merit
priority by virtue of their economic and social relevance (such as information
technology and biotechnology). But this may lead government research
organisations to be so susceptible to changes in national priorities and needs
that it may invalidate or fundamentally alter their research missions. In
addition to forming linkages with industry to further the diffusion of
knowledge, universities and laboratories are more frequently asked to directly
contribute to problem solving in technological investigations. Despite
its generic character, the science system has always been important for
generating knowledge about fruitful opportunities and practical dead-ends in
more applied research and for contributing directly to strategic or commercial
outcomes. This problem-solving function is being given more emphasis in the
knowledge-based economy. For example, the advent of flexible manufacturing
systems has created new demands for scientific insights into materials,
production processes and even management. The growing preponderance in economic
output of service industries requires scientific knowledge on organisational
improvements and networking to sustain productivity advances. Similarly, much of
the new information and communication technologies are science-based, and
science still has much to offer to help these technologies maximise their
contributions to production and employment.
In part because of its
increased importance in the knowledge-based economy, the science system finds
itself torn between more traditional areas of research and investigations that
promise more immediate returns. Many argue that if scientists are to create the
knowledge that will generate the new technologies of the next century, they
should be encouraged to have their own ideas, not continue with those that
industry already has. There should be sufficient scope to allow scientists to
set research directions guided by their own curiosity, even when these are not
seen as immediately valuable to industry. On the other hand, some of the most
important scientific insights have come from the solution of industrial
problems. The knowledge-based economy is raising the profile of the science
system, but also leading to a more intense probing of its fundamental
identity.
Even though we know the
contributions of the science system to the production, transmission and transfer
of knowledge, there has not been great progress in measuring the extent of these
contributions. A related problem is establishing a standard of accountability
for public research funding, a problem that is of growing significance for
future government support of the science system. Although there is widespread
belief that public funding for scientific research has produced substantial
benefits, there is concern with how these benefits may be measured and related
to funding levels.
Efforts to measure the
contribution of scientific knowledge to the economy are difficult for
several reasons. First, because most scientific knowledge is freely disclosed,
it is hard to trace its use and therefore its benefits as it is employed within
private economic activities. Second, the results of scientific investigation are
often enabling rather than directly applicable to technological innovation,
further obscuring any overt trace of their beneficial impact. Third, new
scientific knowledge may save resources that would otherwise be spent in
exploring scientific or technological dead-ends and
27
these resource savings are not observed. As a result, cost-benefit analysis, a leading method for evaluation of public investments, is likely to understate the benefits of scientific research.
Efforts to more precisely
define and measure the science system are occurring in an era of growing public
financial stringency throughout the OECD countries. Current indicators offer
little assistance in addressing the overall impact of science on the economy
or for evaluating how funding allocations should be made between newly
developing and established fields of investigation. The need for a better
understanding of the contributions of the science system to OECD economies is
heightened by debates about the nature of scientific knowledge and the role of
governments.
Adding to, and
complicating, these issues is the evolving role of the science system in
diffusing and transferring knowledge to the private sector to enhance economic
growth and competitiveness. The challenge for the science system, and for
governments, is to adapt to its new role in the knowledge-based economy while
not losing sight of the essential need for sufficient levels of pure, generic
non-commercial research.
28