0. Global GDP Comparisons
CIA World Fact Book (The
World Factbook - The World Factbook (cia.gov);
Forbes Tax Burden;
The Global Economy
1. Comparative Advantage, Competitiveness
& Fitness (MKM C/3 53-58:
52-56;
54-60)
If the production function is the most elegant contribution to
thought by economics, i.e., Y = f (K, L, N), then the
theory of comparative advantage is one of its most obscure.
When challenged by mathematician Stanislaw Ulam to “name me one
proposition in all of the social sciences which is both true and
non-trivial,” the Nobel Prize winning economist Paul Samuelson
responded with the theory of comparative advantage because:
"That it is logically true need not be argued before a
mathematician; that it is not trivial is attested by the thousands
of important and intelligent men who have never been able to grasp
the doctrine for themselves or to believe it after it was explained
to them (Samuelson 1969)."
This obscurity partially results because the theory engages a
complex web of economic ideas including
absolute advantage,
division and specialization of labour,
division of labour limited by the size of the market, exchange,
factor endowments,
opportunity cost,
production possibility frontiers,
relative prices, separation of consumption from production and
trade. Furthermore, it would more accurately be called the
theory of comparative cost rather than of advantage. And, of
course, some of its results appear counter-intuitive.
Semantic obscurity has lead to the theory finding general expression
as a numeric example such as that first used by David Ricardo to
demonstrate the theory in his 1817 book
The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. In his case, it
concerned wheat and wine production in England and Portugal.
In summary, comparative advantage means that mutually beneficial
exchange is possible whenever relative production costs differ prior
to trade. One of its counter-intuitive deductions, however, is
that if a country enjoys an absolute advantage in the production of
all goods and services, i.e., can produce all of them cheaper
than anyone else, it is still better off trading with other
countries. The theory was used by Ricardo to counter arguments
in favour of protective tariffs and trade barriers which,
intuitively, promise national prosperity. It continues to
serve this free-trade purpose. The theory attributes the cause
and benefits of international trade to the differences among
countries in the opportunity cost (cost in terms of other goods
given up) of producing the same commodities. In Ricardo's
theory, labour was the only factor of production. Furthermore,
according to Ricardo, the fact that one country could produce
everything more efficiently than another was not an argument against
international trade.
The
theory of comparative advantage, in effect, separates consumption
from production. Without trade, a nation can only consume what
it produces. With trade, it is able to consume
more than it produces. Put another way, by specializing in
what it does best, a nation can afford to buy more of what it does
worst. There are, however, limits - see: Ideological
Evolution: Ch. 14 - Competitiveness,
14.4 - Comparative Advantage.
The theory of comparative advantage provides a
strong argument in favour of free international trade and specialization among
countries. For clarity, the theory is usually first outlined as though
only two countries and only two commodities are involved, although the
principles are by no means limited to such cases. Consider the production
possibility frontier (PPF) of 'Farmland' (P&B
Fig. 35.1; MKM Figs, 2.2, 2.3, 3.1 & 3.2). If all resources were
committed to producing grain then 36 millions tons would result. If all
resources were committed to producing cars some 9 million cars would be
produced. The PPF shows the alternative amounts of grain or cars that
could be produced if resources were divided between these two activities.
The slope of the PPF measures the 'opportunity cost' of producing one car
measured by how many tons of grain could not be produced.
By way of contrast consider the PPF of Mobilia
(P&B
Fig. 35.2). If all resources were committed to grain then 19
tons would be produced; if all resources were committed to cars, then about 10
million cars would come off the production line. As above the slope of the
PPF measures the opportunity cost of producing cars vs grain.
In both cases, a country chooses which combination
of the two goods to produce and consume. For Farmland it is assumed to be
15 tons of grain and 8 million cars. For Mobilia, it is 18 million tons of
grain and 4 million cars. This mix of outputs assumes no international
trade between the two. The production/consumption mix must be on the PPF.
Cars are cheaper in Mobilia (one car costs one ton
of grain compared to 9 tons in Farmland; grain is cheaper in Farmland (9 tons
cost one car compared to nine cars in Mobilia). Each has a comparative
advantage in one commodity where comparative advantage is defined as the ability
to produce a given good or service cheaper than another country. If
they were to trade both would benefit. Mobilia would get cheaper grain and
Farmland would get cheaper cars.
First considering only international trade in cars. Farmland has a demand curve
reflecting the quantity of imported cars it would be willing to buy at various
prices (measured in tons of grain - P&B
Fig. 35.3). If the price were the same as the domestic cost of
production (9 tons) no cars would be imported. At any price less that that
some cars would be imported. For Mobilia there is a supply curve of cars
it would be willing to sell at various prices (measured in tons of grain).
If the price were the same as the cost of domestic production (1 ton) the
Mobilia would not trade. At any price higher than the domestic cost of
production it would be willing to trade. Where demand equals supply
exchange takes place at a price of 3 tons of grain 4 million cars will be
imported into Farmland and 12 million tons of grain exported to Mobilia.
In this exchange it is assumed a balance of trade will result.
The effect of trade is to move the consumption
possibility curve off and away from the PPF (P&B
Fig. 35.4). The consumption possibility curve reflects the 'terms of trade',
i.e. 3 tons of grain for 1 car. Where this curve is tangent to each
countries PPF marks the new output combination. For Farmland 30 tons of
grain and 5 million cars; for Mobilia, 9 tons of grain and 9 million cars.
However, due to trade each can now consume more than before trade. Thus
Farmland now consumes 18 million tons of grain an 9 million cars (compared to 15
million tons of grain and 8 million cars without trade); and Mobilia now
consumes 21 million tons of grain and 5 million cars (compared to 18 tons of
grain and 4 million cars without trade). Both are better off.
Even if one country has an 'absolute advantage' in
both commodities, it still pays to trade. The reason is opportunity cost.
Thus while output may be greater for the same level of inputs in one country,
there remains an opportunity cost to producing one vs. the other commodity.
As long as the opportunity cost of another country is less it still pays to
trade.
There is no doubt that competitiveness in the
division and specialization of labour available through free trade leads to a
higher level of consumption and hence well-being of domestic consumers.
Similarly, there is no doubt that some industries win and some lose in a given
nation creating lobbying forces in favour and against trade. But
competitiveness in the form of comparative advantage has its limits.
Competitiveness is generally expressed in sports
metaphors such as: “skating where the puck is going, not where it is” which
captures its anticipative nature (Wilson 1992). In this game, however, some win
and some lose in an “us/them” conflict deciding the destiny of our children, our
communities and our country. Arguably, global competitiveness has ideologically
quenched the last embers of the ‘60s revolution of rising expectations. Fear of
job loss has smothered the hopes of citizen consumers and workers. Instead of
George H. Bush Sr.’s “kinder and gentler society”, we live with George W. Bush
Jr.s fear of downsizing, obsolescence, out sourcing, privatization, redundancies
and technological displacement.
In sports, it is the opposing team that is the
challenge. The playing field, the environment itself, is generally fixed,
invariant and subsidiary to the consciousness of players at play. In biology,
however, natural selection involves not just an opponent but also new invariants
and affordances thrown up by an ever changing environment including predator,
prey, possible mates and/or symbionts (Grene
& Depew 2004). Environmental invariants become subsidiary or 'tacit'
to our focal awareness of affordances. In this view, 'knowledge' is orientation
in an environment resulting from the tacit integration of subsidiary and focal
awareness into a gestalt whole (Polanyi Oct. 1962) called 'knowing' one's
'fitness landscape'.
In fact, comparative advantage is a natural
phenonmenon:
Economics has its roots in agency and the emergence
of advantages of trade among autonomous agents. The advantages of
trade predate the human economy by essentially the entire history of
life on this planet. Advantages of trade are found in the metabolic
exchange of legume root nodule and fungi, sugar for fixed nitrogen
carried in amino acids. Advantages of trade were found among the
mixed microbial and algal communities along the littoral of the
earth’s oceans four billion years ago. The trading of the
econosphere is an outgrowth of the trading of the biosphere. (Kauffman
2000, 211)
To demonstrate the advantages of
trade, Kauffman uses a biological example that, to my mind at least,
is intuitive:
Consider two bacterial species, red
and blue. Suppose the red species secretes a red metabolite, at
metabolic cost to itself, that aids the replication rate of the blue
species. Conversely, suppose the blue species secretes a different
blue metabolite, at metabolic cost to itself, that increases the
replication rate of the red species. Then the conditions for a
mutualism are possible. Roughly stated, if blue helps red more than
it costs itself, and vice versa, a mixed community of blue and red
bacteria may grow. How will it happen? And is there an optimal
“exchange rate” of blue-secreted metabolite to red-secreted
metabolite, where that exchange rate is the analogue of price? (Kauffman
2000, 216-17)
How it will happen and at what rate it will happen is
determined by coevolution. The benefits of trade lead each to adjust to
the other until optimal growth is achieved by both. Without each others
help, individually, each would be less fit. In such a symbiotic
relationship there is also potentiality for emergence of a higher order
autonomous agent, e.g., prokaryotes coevolving into eukaryotes.
Given such an active environment, autonomous agents –
organisms or institutions – constantly adapt, adjust and evolve or go
extinct. They adapt by experimenting with mutations called
preadaptations or exaptations. According to Kauffman, these come from
the adjacent possible consisting “of all those molecular species that
are not members of the actual, but are one reaction step away from the
actual” (Kauffman 2000, 142). In the noösphere, it is those new ideas
generated by 'research & development' in the natural & engineering
sciences, new ideologies generated by the humanities & social sciences
including the so-called management sciences and by the new aesthetics,
forms and designs thrown up by the Arts. Economic, epistemic and
biological systems expand or explore the adjacent possible as quickly as
possible subject to timely selection of the fit and unfit, e.g., going
out of business. Such timely selection is called ‘early visibility’ and
‘fast failing’ in the innovation literature (The Economist Oct. 11,
2007).
If selection takes too long, then fitness may decline or
simply melt away. Arguably, this explains ‘de-industrialization’ of the
Anglosphere. They maintained existing plant and equipment, e.g., in
steel production, until fully depreciated through voluntary (and
sometimes involuntary) quotas on imports from developing Asian producers
who were investing in the best new technologies emerging from the
adjacent possible. The fitness of the West, or rather the Anglosphere,
fell, at least in terms of the traditional manufacturing-based economy.
In this sense Darwinian fitness is not simply bodily strength,
intelligence, vigor or bravery vis-à-vis rivals. Rather, fitness is a
compounded result of the mutual relationship between an organism and its
environment including symbiotic as well as predator/prey relationships.
And symbionts can significantly enhance fitness, i.e.,
the probability one will survive and leave descendants. Arguably this
is what the European Union and to a lesser extent what NAFTA represent:
the symbiotic survival of the nation-state in a global knowledge-based
economy.
For a more detailed analysis, please see my assessment of
the changing sands of sovereignty upon which the modern
Nation-State rest as well as my comparison
between competitiveness and 'fitness'
as a test:
2. Exports, Imports, Deficit & Surplus
(MKM Ch. 12 all editions)
Exports are what we sell and imports are what we buy from other
countries. The balance of trade is the difference between our
exports and imports. If imports exceed exports there is a 'trade
deficit' that must be financed by borrowing from abroad or selling
off assets. If exports exceed imports there is a 'trade surplus'
and the difference can be used to lend to other countries or buy
assets. As will be seen trade in goods & services makes up the bulk
of the 'current account' with other countries. There is also a
'capital account'. Together - capital and current - constitute the
'balance of payments'.
What we buy and sell includes goods and services. Goods are fairly
straight forward. They essential include things produced by the
primary and secondary sectors of the economy. The primary sector
includes farming, fishing, forestry and mining industries. The
secondary sector involves the manufacturing industries. The
tertiary sector involves services are a little more complex. Some
are fairly obvious like tourism and transportation, e.g. a Canadian
goes to France and stays in a hotel, buys restaurant food, etc. and
this counts as an import; a French person comes to Canada and does
the same and it counts as an export. As they say: follow the
money. Some services are more intangible like banking and
management services, engineering and design services as well as the
flow of intellectual property royalties. Furthermore, with multi-
or trans-national corporations there is the problem of
intra-corporate transfer pricing which involves, among other things,
maximum avoidance of tax given the different jurisdictions in which
they operate.
Canada's pattern of trade is dominated by the U.S., both with
respect to imports and exports. China, Japan and the UK are our
next most important export markets. While our exports flow
principally from the primary industries, secondary and tertiary
industries are slowly growing as export players. We are no longer
just "hewers of wood and drawers of water". By contrast our imports
are dominated by secondary and tertiary sectors. However, it is
increasingly from the 'quaternary sector', i.e. royalties on
intellectual property rights (IPRs) which constitute the legal
foundation for the industrial organization of a knowledge-based
economy. The evolution of the multilateral intellectual and
cultural property rights regime is traced out in one of my
articles. I will, in class, outline the nature of IPRs.
3. Free, Fair & Sanctioned Trade and Restrictions (MKM Ch. 13,
318; 299; 309)
Prior to WW II the global economy was dominated by Nation-States and
European colonial empires seeking autarky or self-sufficiency in
both production and consumption. To protect or develop (infant
industry argument) domestic producers Governments erected trade
barriers in the form of tariffs and quotas. A tariff is a per unit
tax imposed on imported goods. It is collected by the Government
and, prior to the war, tariffs were a major public revenue source.
Quotas, on the other hand, are quantitative limits on how many units
of a good may be imported. No revenue is collected by the
Government. Rather, importers buy at world price but, due to
restricted supply, sell at a higher price pocketing the profit.
During the Great Depression countries threw up tariff and quota
barriers while subsidizing the exports of domestic producers. This
was known as the 'beggar thy neighbour' policy.
With
the end of WW II the market economies agreed on the General
Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) in 1947. While the Communist
world formed the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (COMECON)
and traded on a material balances basis, GATT members were market
economies. As will be seen with creation of the WTO in 1995,
virtually all national economies were or became market economies,
e.g., the People’s Republic of China joined the WTO in 2001.
With
GATT countries began a long process of reducing both tariffs and
quotas to gain the benefits of trade for their consumers. The
diagram below shows the decline in tariff s.
a) Tariffs (MBB Fig. 16.9; P&B
7th Ed Fig. 7.5 & 7.6)
Let us examine the impact of tariffs and quotas. First, tariffs.
Consider Fig. 7.5 (a). World price is $5, opposed to an $8 price
for domestic product. At that price demand is 6 million units as
opposed to 4 million without trade. The consumer benefit is
obvious. But what about domestic producers? It should be recalled
that the blue Supply Curve displayed is a horizontal summation of
how much each domestic firm is willing to produce at each price and
break even in the long run. Domestic firms that can compete are
those below the $5 price. Other domestic firms are forced out of
business.
While the consumer benefits of free trade are obvious but diffuse
the costs are borne directly by domestic producers and their
employees who do not want to go out of business or lose their jobs.
In response to lobbying by the afflicted Government imposes a $2 per
unit tariff displayed in Fig. 7.5 (b). In effect this raises the
domestic price to $7 per unit. Domestic producers between $5 and $7
can stay in business. Consumer, however, now pay more than world
price and the benefits of trade are reduced. With the tariff 1
million units are imported and the Government earns $2 million in
revenue (the grey rectangle). Fig. 7.6 shows the winners and losers
from a tariff. Deadweight loss is not, however, testable
.
b)
Quota
(MKM Ch. 13, 318; 299; 309)
And now, quotas. Consider Fig. 7.7 (a) & (b). Under free trade the
outcome is world price $5 as opposed to an $8 price for domestic
product. At that price demand is 6 million units as opposed to 4
million without trade. The consumer benefit is obvious. But what
about domestic producers? Again, the blue Supply Curve displayed is
a horizontal summation of how much each domestic firm is willing to
produce at each price and break even in the long run. Domestic
firms that can compete are those below the $5 price. Other domestic
firms are forced out of business.
Again while the consumer benefits of free trade are obvious but
diffuse the costs are borne directly by domestic producers and their
employees who do not want to go out of business or lose their jobs.
In response to lobbying by the afflicted Government imposes a quota
of 1 million units displayed in Fig. 7.7 (b). In effect this raises
the domestic price to $7 per unit by shifting the supply curve to
the right, i.e., a limited increase in supply. Domestic
producers between $5 and $7 can stay in business. Importers buy at
world price ($5) but sells domestically for $7 pocketing the
profit. Consumer, however, now pay more than world price and the
benefits of trade are reduced. Fig. 7.8 shows the winners and losers from a tariff.
Again, deadweight loss is not, however, testable.
The trend to free trade resulting in tariff and quota reductions to maximize
the benefits of trade seemed unstoppable until the Trump
presidency. Many textbooks have thus reduced consideration of
tariffs and quotas to one line definitions. They were considered
obsolete.
P&B
7th Ed Fig. 7.7 &
7.8)
c) Non-Tariff Barriers:
Not Testable
As tariffs and quotas fell alternative
forms of trade restrictions flowered. These included restrictions
based on, among other things, culture, environment, health, national
security, product standards and public safety. All are, relative to
the hard dollars & cents of tariffs and quotas, vague, amorphous
terms open to interpretation and game playing. Similarly,
definition of ‘subsidy’ continues to elude the World Trade
Organization (WTO). In the face of such non-tariff barriers the WTO
is, as of March 2020, grinding to a halt.
A new era in international trade is
dawning. The era of ‘free trade’ defined as tariff and quota free
trade is over. The era of ‘fair trade’ that takes account of
non-tariff barriers is dawning as has the age of sanctions.
Critical Global Trade Dates
1898 Spanish American War
1905 Russian-Japanese War
1914-18 WWI
1917 Russian Revolution
1920 League of Nations
1922 Mussolini comes to power
1929-1939 Great Depression
1933 USA Ends Gold Standard
&
Hitler Comes to Power
1937 Japan invades China
1939-45 WWII
1944 Breton Woods, Institutional Architecture of International
Trade & Finance and Return of Gold Standard
1945 UN
Cold War 1945-1991
1947 GATT
1949
Comecon
1955-1975 Vietnam War
1964-65 LBJ's Great Society
1971 End of USA Gold Standard
1974 Petrodollar
1991 Collapse of the Soviet
Union
1995 WTO
2001
China enters WTO,
BRICS &
Shanghai Cooperation
Organisation
2022 Russia-NATO War
4. The WTO, the Global Knowledge-Based Economy
&
BRICS
Not Testable
In 1995 the World Trade Organization (WTO) began operations and a
new global economy was born. Today, 2018, virtually all member
states of the United Nations (UN) belong to the WTO. Put another
way, global regulation by the UN of political and military
competition in 1945 was extended to global regulation of economic
competition by the WTO fifty years later. This was possible only
because of the global triumph of the Market over Marx. In this
regard, formation of the WTO arguably represents the high water mark
of international influence and power of the United States and its
market economy.
For the first time, virtually all nation-states agreed to abide by
common rules of trade recognizing the WTO as final arbitrator of
disputes and authorizing it to sanction countervailing measures
against offenders of its rules. Given the historical role of trade
disputes fuelling international conflict, the WTO compliments the UN
as a bulwark of international peace, law and order. A key question
not answered by the WTO Treaty is the definition of a 'subsidy' and
'national security'. Disputes between Member States are settled by
a tribunal of experts in the matter in dispute. If an offending
Member is found to have broken WTO rules and a complaining Member
has suffered damages then countervailing tariffs equal to the
assessed damages may be placed on imports of the offending Member.
Such 'countervails' can be selectively applied to any imports from
the offending Member.
As an international legal instrument, the WTO is a ‘single
undertaking’, i.e., it is a set of instruments constituting a single
package permitting only a single signature without reservation. One
of these instruments is the Trade-Related Intellectual Properties
and Services Agreement (TRIPS, WTO 1994) that constitutes, in
effect, a global agreement on trade in knowledge, or more precisely,
in intellectual property rights (IPRs) such as copyrights, patents,
registered industrial designs and trademarks. TRIPS is, however,
but one part of the complex WTO package that includes the General
Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and twenty-six other technical
agreements.
TRIPS, in turn, exists in the context of a constellation of
international agreements, conventions, covenants and treaties
administered by the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO
1979) a special subject agency of the United Nations. TRIPS
requires accession to some but not to all WIPO instruments. In
turn, WIPO instruments apply only to Nations-States that accede to
them. Generally, acceding States provide only ‘national treatment’
to citizens of other States, i.e., the same rights are extended as
if they were nationals but the rights so extended are defined by
each national legislature. This treatment contrasts with
‘harmonization’, characteristic of other WTO efforts, e.g.,
definition of subsidies. Currently ‘in force’ WIPO instruments, as
well as TRIPS, ignore and thereby deny protection to
‘non-marketable’ intellectual property rights, e.g., aboriginal
heritage rights (Farrer 1994; Chartrand 1995) including rights to
traditional ecological knowledge or (TEK) as well as collective or
community-based intellectual property rights in general (Shiva
1993). Such ignored rights, together with commercial rights that
have lapsed through time, constitute the public domain of knowledge
from which any and all may freely draw.
In 1996, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
(OECD), whose members constitute the First World of developed,
democratic market economies, published The Knowledge-Based Economy
(OECD 1996). The next year the OECD published guidelines for
competitiveness in this new economy: National Innovation Systems
(OECD 1997).
Creation of the WTO and recognition of the knowledge-based economy
by the OECD initiated an avalanche of change. Almost immediately,
rapid institution building began, continuing to this day, in public
and private sectors around the world. A new specialty emerged –
‘knowledge management’, not to be confused with its predecessor -
information management; the ‘Chief Knowledge Officer’ (CKO) is
becoming an hierarchical feature of multi- and trans-national
corporations; governments are creating knowledge ministries,
departments and agencies; ‘knowledge audits’ are being conducted by
firms and nation-states around the world (Malhorta 2000); and,
nation-states themselves are designing ‘national innovation systems’
(NIS) to generate and market new knowledge (OECD 1997). Even a
standardized lexicon or vocabulary is being drafted to guide public
and private sector discussion and debate (American National
Standards Institute and the Global Knowledge Economics Council
2001).
Only time will tell whether all this conceptual and institutional
activity is a passing policy fad or marks a true evolutionary leap
in economic development and thinking. What is certain is that
knowledge is now recognized as a strategic asset in the
competitiveness of nations. What is equally certain, however, is
that the ‘Standard Model’ of economic thought is theoretically
inadequate to deal with this new economy.
Non-linked references
Farrer, C.,“Who
Owns the Words? An Anthropological Perspective of Public Law
101-601,” Journal of Arts Management, Law and Society,
Winter 1994, 317-326.
Samuelson, P.A., “The Way of an Economist,” in P.A.
Samuelson, ed., International Economic Relations: Proceedings of
the Third Congress of the International Economic Association,
Macmillan, London, 1969.
Shiva, V., Monocultures of the Mind: Understanding
the Threats to Biological and Cultural Diversity, Inaugural
Hooper Lecture, Centre of International Programs, University of
Guelph, September 21, 1993.
Wilson, M., “Address to the
Canadian Bureau for International Education,” July 14, 1992.
|