1. Balance of Payments (MKM
C12/281; 264; 273)
The balance of
payments is the score sheet for all economic transactions during a given
period between one country and its residents
(including Government) and all other countries. Transactions are
reported using double entry
bookkeeping with credit entries balanced on the debit side, and vice versa. The
balance of payments thus necessarily balances. There can be no
surplus or deficit in a country's balance of payments as a whole.
A country's
balance of payments
is divided into two major sections: the
current account and the capital account. The current account, in turn, is subdivided into goods and
services and transfer payments. The capital account is subdivided into
non-monetary
(sale/purchase of real assets) and monetary (payment for work) sectors.
The balance of payments is part of the System of National Accounts (MBB Fig. 17.1- Canada).
The
overall balance of payments comprises the current account (merchandise and
services), unilateral transfers (gifts, grants, remittances, and so on), and the
capital account (long-term and short-term capital movements). If payments due in
exceed those due out, a country is said to be in surplus; and when
payments due out exceed payments due in, it is in deficit. The surplus
or deficit must be balanced by a monetary movement in the opposite direction. Consequently the overall balance must be
equal, i.e., an accounting identity.
It
is important to distinguish the 'trade balance' and the balance of payments.
The trade balance refers to trade in goods & services (sometimes considered
separately, goods vs. services). An export surplus or deficit
in goods (merchandising trade account) may be matched by net sales of services
(service account). There would then
be no deficit in goods and services as a whole. Thus the balance
of payments is a broader
and more significant measure than is the balance of trade in goods and/or
services.
In turn, the trade balance
is different than the current account balance. A nation with a current account
deficit is ipso facto decreasing its capital assets abroad (including gold) or
increasing capital liabilities to foreigners. A nation with a
current-account surplus is gaining foreign assets or reducing foreign
liabilities.
A deficit in the
trade balance does not necessarily affect a
country's exchange rate. There may be a matching inflow of investment capital
that strengthens the immediate exchange position and builds up a country's
future exporting capacity. Similarly, a surplus in the trade balance does not assure a strong exchange rate.
For other explanations see: The Economist
Glossary -
Balance of Payments; Government of Canada
Balance of Payments; Statistics Canada Wikipedia
Balance of Payments;
Balance of Payments Accounts: Definitions
2.
Exchange Rate (MKM C13/ 286-291: 268-272;
278-282)
The
'exchange rate' is the price of a country's money in relation to another
country's money. Generally
when Canada's exports increase, the
exchange rate increases, i.e., fewer Canadian dollars buy a unit of foreign
currency. Increased foreign demand for Canadian currency makes
Canadian goods more expensive. As Canadian goods become more expensive,
exports decline. Decreased demand for the Canadian dollar then
tends to lower the exchange rate making Canadian goods cheaper and so on
and so on in a floating exchange rate system. The current floating
exchange rate system is 'managed' by agreement among the larger central banks.
Accordingly, a currency may rise or fall within some limit with respect to
another, say 10%. No intervention is required. If a currency rises
or falls more then central bank action may be taken to strengthen or weaken a
given currency in exchange markets. It important to note
that the foreign exchange market is, in the main, binary, i.e.,
there is market for the $Cdn and the $US and a separate market for the $Cdn
and the British £ and yet another for the $Cdn and the European €.
Accordingly, while a national currency is the
generally accepted medium of exchange, unit of account, store of value and
income earning asset within a given country, it is just another commodity on the
currency exchange market being bought and sold like pork bellies, soybeans and
other goods & services.
(a)
Dollar
Demand (P&B 7th
Ed Fig. 25.2)
Like
any commodity the Canadian dollar is subject to the Law of Demand:
higher the price lower the demand; lower the price greater the demand.
From where does this demand emerge? Three factors affect demand: (i)
global demand for Canadian goods & services, a.k.a., exports; (ii) the differential
between Canadian and foreign interest rates; and, (iii) the expected
future exchange rate. The existing curve embodies current demand
factors. Change in a plotted variable causes movement along the
curve. A change in any of the three demand factors causes the
curve to shift
(P&B
7th
Ed Fig. 25.5; R&L 13th Ed
Fig. 35-3)
.
(i) Global Demand
If global
demand for Canadian goods & services increases then more dollars must be
bought on the foreign exchange market by foreign buyers. Quite simply,
foreign currency is not a generally accepted medium of exchange within a
country. Accordingly, a foreign buyer must first exchange foreign
currency for Canadian dollars and then purchase Canadian exports. This
is the foresign exchange market. If demand for Canadian goods &
services goes up the demand curve shifts to the right; if export demand
goes down the demand curve shifts to the left. The exchange rate
accordingly rises and falls in response to changes in demand.
(ii)
Interest Rate Differential
Investors are
concerned with the ‘real’ rate of return and the ‘real’ interest rate.
At a given point in time the nominal interest rate in a country is say
6%. Inflation, however, is running at an annual rate of 3%. The ‘real’
interest rate is 6 – 3 = 3%. Similarly, at a given point in time, the
‘real’ interest rate in country A is 6% while 3% in country B. The
interest differential will encourage investors in B to shift monies to A
where they can earn a higher real interest rate. This would represent a
capital account inflow to A and outflow from B.
If the differential
increases, there will be new demand for currency A shifting A’s
currency demand curve to the right. Investors must first acquire
currency A on the exchange market before they can complete the
transaction, i.e., increased demand for currency A. If the
differential shrinks, so does demand for currency A and its demand curve
shifts to the left. Assuming a fixed supply curve the exchange rate
will rise in the first case and fall in the second.
(iii) Expected Future
Exchange Rate
The demand for dollars is like that for
any commodity. If one expects its price to rise tomorrow one runs out
and buys it today, i.e., an increase in demand shifting the curve
to the right. Similarly, if one expects the price (the exchange rate)
to fall tomorrow one holds off purchasing today, i.e., a decrease
in demand and the curve shift to the left. Assuming a fixed supply
curve, the exchange rate rises in the first case and falls in the
second.
(b) Dollar
Supply (P&B
7th
Ed Fig. 25.3; R&L 13th Ed
Fig. 35-3)
Like any commodity the Canadian dollar is subject to the Law of Supply:
higher the price greater the supply; lower the price lower the supply.
The supply of dollars to the foreign
exchange market has several sources. The central bank keeps reserves of
foreign currencies so do the chartered banks and some other deposit
taking institutions. Some large
multinational corporations also have foreign currency reserves on hand.
Furthermore, there are currency traders and speculators like George
Soros – the man who broke the Bank of England and remains subject to
arrest in Malaysia. Currency speculation involve predicting changes in
exchange rates – buy cheap, sell high. In the case of smaller economies
currency speculators can cause exchange rates to rise or fall depending
on their profit position thereby upsetting such economies, e.g.,
the
Asian financial crisis of 1997-98 that saw the Thai and then other
southeast Asian economies to go into deep recession.
Three factors affect supply: (i) Canadian
imports; (ii) the differential between Canadian and foreign interest
rates; and, (iii) the expected future exchange rate.
(P&B
7th
Ed Fig. 25.6)
(i)
Canadian Imports
If imports to Canada increase then
Canadian dollars must be spent on the currency exchange market to buy
foreign currencies with which to complete the transaction. This
increases the supply of Canadian dollars and the supply curve shifts to
the right. If imports decline fewer Canadian dollars are spent on
foreign currency and the supply curve shifts to the left. Assuming a
fixed demand curve the exchange rate will fall in the first instance and
rise in the second.
(ii) Interest Rate
Differential
At a given point in time, the ‘real’
interest rate in country A is 6% while 3% in country B. The interest
differential will encourage investors in B to
shift monies to A where they can earn a
higher real interest rate. This would be a capital account inflow to A
and outflow from B. If the differential increases, there will be new
supply of currency B in the currency exchange market shifting B’s
currency supply curve to the right. Investors must first acquire
currency B on the exchange market before they can complete the
transaction, i.e., increased supply of currency B. If the differential
shrinks, so does supply of currency B shifts to the left. Assuming a
fixed supply curve the exchange rate will falls in the first case and
rises in the second.
(iii) Expected Future
Exchange Rate
The supply of dollars is like that for
any commodity. If one expects its price to rise tomorrow one
waits, i.e., an decrease in supply shifting the curve
to the left. Similarly, if one expects the price (the exchange rate)
to fall tomorrow one sells today, i.e., an increase
in supply and the curve shift to the righ. Assuming a fixed demand
curve, the exchange rate rises in the first case and falls in the
second.
(c)
Equilibrium Exchange Rate (P&B
7th
Ed Fig. 25.4; R&L 13th Ed
Fig. 35-1)
All things being
fixed there will be, at a point in time, a demand and supply of dollars
on the foreign exchange market. Again, this market is binary, Canadian
dollars for US dollars; Canadian dollars for British pounds, etc.
Where the willingness to buy meets the willingness to sell a stable
market equilibrium is created. If the exchange rate rises above
equilibrium supply exceeds demand and a surplus is created resolved by a
lowering of the price. If the rate drops below equilibrium demand
exceeds supply and a shortage is created resolved by bidding the price
back up to equilibrium. That equilibrium, however, depends on the
constancy of exports, imports, interest rate differentials and
expectation of the future exchange rate. Change these and you shift the
curves.
(d) Market Intervention (P&B
7th
Ed Fig. 25.7)
As previously noted, the current floating
exchange rate system is 'managed' by agreement among the larger central
banks. Accordingly, a currency may rise or fall within some limit with
respect to another, say 10%. No intervention is required. If a
currency exchange rate rises (appreciation of a currency) or falls
(depreciation of a currency) beyond 10% then central bank action will be
required to strengthen or weaken its currency in exchange markets. How?
By buying or selling its currency on the foreign exchange market.
Sometimes the actions of a given central
bank is simply insufficient. In the short run larger central banks may
then coordinate the buying and selling of a given currency to
re-establish market equilibrium. If the problem persists then either a
new range may agreed upon, say 15%, or the World Bank and/or
International Monetary Fund may provide financial support in exchange
for structural and other changes to the domestic economy in distress.
Sometimes governments resort to exchange
controls (sometimes combined with import licensing) to allocate foreign
exchange more or less directly in payment for specific imports. At
times, a considerable apparatus is assembled for this purpose, and,
despite "leakages" of various kinds, the system has proved reasonably
efficient in achieving balance on external payments account. Its chief
disadvantage is that it interferes with normal market processes, thereby
encouraging rigidities in the economy, reinforcing vested interests and
restricting the growth of world trade. On the other hand, some
countries, e.g., Argentina, will impose an export tax to keep domestic
prices low.
Whatever method is chosen, the process of
adjustment is generally supervised by some central authority -- the
central bank or some institution closely associated with it -- that can
assemble the information necessary to ensure that the proper responses
are made to changing conditions.
Also see: The Economist Glossary -
Exchange Rate; Wikipedia -
Exchange Rate;
3. Trade & The
Domestic Economy
As we have seen a closed or autarkic economy without
foreign trade can only consume what it produces. It is stuck on its
production possibility frontier. Similarly, investment (I) in a closed
economy is exclusively dependent upon domestic savings (S), i.e.,
I = S. Similarly, the domestic money supply must equal domestic demand
for money, i.e., Ms = Md
In an open economy, however, some domestic savings will
be invested in foreign economies and some foreign savings will be
invested in the domestic economy. Canadian investment abroad represents
a leakage from the circular flow of income. In effect, Ms is reduced
with implications for domestic interest rates (r) and hence investment.
Foreign investment in Canada, on the other hand, represents an injection
that, in effect, increases Ms with reversed implications. The overall
effect depends upon the net of injections minus leakages, i.e.,
does Ms go up or down and hence does r go down or up and therefore does
I go up or down? The monetary transmission mechanism at work.
The net effect of capital flows in and out of a domestic
economy is of concern to both the Central Bank and the elected
Government. How do short- and long-run capital flows affect AD/AS
short- and long-run equilibrium, the exchange rate, the interest rate,
the inflation rate, the balance of payments (BOP)? What tools are
available to Government and its Central Bank, alone or in a co-ordinated
fashion, to manage short-run fluctuations and foster long-run national
economic growth?
At any point in time the first question is: What is the
current state of the economy?
P&B 7th edition
(a) Fiscal Policy
Fiscal policy
involves the taxing and spending power of the elected Government. What
is important is that these powers are distributional in nature and can
target specific sectors of the economy. Consider the balance of trade
in goods & services. To promote exports and reduce a trade deficit
Government can create a publicly owned export development bank to
provide financing and other services to exporters. It can support
industrial trade missions. It can subsidize domestic producers. The
spending power at work. Alternatively, Government can exempt exports
from sales & excise taxes. It can provide income tax and other special
tax regimes to foster exports. It can impose tariffs and quotas on
imported goods. The taxing power at work.
(b) Monetary Policy
Monetary policy involves Central Bank management of the
money supply and therefore interest rates as well as maintaining the
stability of the currency at home and abroad. Tools include changing
bank reserve requirement, the banker’s rate, open market operations,
account shifting and moral suasion.
Consider capital flight when large amounts of foreign
investment leave a country over a short time period. The sale of the
domestic currency increases its supply on foreign exchange markets
shifting the supply curve to the right. This causes the exchange rate
to drop below the desired level. The Central Bank can respond by
entering the foreign exchange market buying domestic currency increasing
demand shifting the demand curve to the right raising the exchange rate
back to the targeted level. At the same time the Central Bank can
reduce the domestic money supply thereby raising the interest rate
differential with other investment destinations and attract back foreign
investment.
These are examples of Government and the Central Bank
acting independently. They could, however, coordinate their
actions. Problems arise when the objectives of the two conflict.
For example, the decline in the exchange rate in the monetary policy
example above makes domestic goods & services cheaper on international
market boosting domestic producers. This gains Government
favourable political capital from domestic industry. The Central
Bank, however, consider the declining exchange rate as bad for the
economy and takes appropriate action. This can, as happened in
Canada during the Coyne Crisis of the 1960s, lead to conflict between
the Government and the Central Bank. The outcome of such a
conflict depends on the degree of independence enjoyed by the Central
Bank.
Introductory Macroeconomics Summary in
8 Graphs |