The Competitiveness of Nations
in a Global Knowledge-Based Economy
H.H. Chartrand
April 2002
Michael Storper
The Limitations to Globalization: Technology Districts
and International Trade
Economic Geography
Volume 68, Issue
1
Jan. 1992,
60-93.
Index
Abstract
Six Propositions on Trade, Flexibility, Technology, and
Regional Development
Export Specialization and Technological
Dynamism
The Increase in Trade
Specialization
Trade and Product-Based Technological
Learning
An Historical Divide?
Developmental Effects: PBTL versus the
Rest
Specialization in Three Countries
Technological Learning and the Organization of
Production
Technology, Evolution, and Increasing
Returns
Problems with Path-dependence and Lock-in: The Division
of Labor
Technological Oligopolists and Production
Networks
The Regional Basis of Technological
Learning
The Global Economy as a Mosaic of
Regions
Networks and Geographical
Agglomerations
Learning and Regional Context: The Qualitative
Specificity of Externalities
The Territorialization of Learning: Regions and
Countries
Flexibility, Technology Districts, and the World
Economy
Flexible Production as a Technological
Trajectory
The Technology District as a Particular Form of the
Industrial District
The Limits to Globalization
References
The
Regional Basis of Technological Learning
The Global Economy as a Mosaic of
Regions
The export specialization industries of the
The existing case study literature suggests that the
geography of the specific subsectors (i.e., of the specializations of each
country) conforms to popular impressions about the “dynamic” regions of these
nations. In the U.S., for example,
more than 50 percent of employment in the export specialization industries
described earlier can be found in eight states (some small and contiguous).
California shows location quotients
of greater than 1.2 for clusters of 4-digit sectors in electronics/computers,
aerospace, instruments, medical equipment, and motion pictures; Texas in
electronics and aircraft; Washington in aircraft and electronic instruments; New
York and New Jersey in pharmaceuticals and electronics; and Massachusetts and
Connecticut in aircraft and machinery, electronics and computers,
telecommunications equipment, precision instruments, medical equipment, R&D,
and aerospace and armaments (Table 7). These areas are, in other words,
concentrations of employment in export-specialized, learning and variety-based,
industries.
In
The geography of French specializations is quite complex
and less well known than the other two countries. A few observations may nonetheless be put
forward. French high technology
specialties in aerospace and defense are concentrated in the
82
Table 7
Technological Districts in the
Source: calculated from data in U.S. Census Bureau, Country
Business Patterns
(
Networks and Geographical
Agglomerations
Vertical disintegration is known to be positively
associated with geographical agglomeration; as the level of external transaction
in a production system grow, and to the extent that those transactional have
geographical cost-structures, the producers caught up in that division of labor
tend to cluster in territorial space in order to reduce the time and cost of
transacting (Scott 1988).
Most of the theory produced on this subject to date
takes as its basic illustration the case of market uncertainty for
producers. Where commands are
uncertain, for any reason, various forms of supplier and subcontracting
relations arise as a way of minimizing unused capacity in the face of
fluctuations. Vertical
disintegration and agglomeration are, in these cases, cost-minimizing strategies
in the face of uncertainty in much the same way they are portrayed in the New
Institutional Economics. Thus, both
agglomeration and disintegration can be present in principle, even in cases when
the production complex is not a PBLT system, including the case where local
uncertainty results from rapid technological change (product and process
redesign) entering the locality from elsewhere, thereby forcing local producers
to hedge their bets by becoming “best-practice imitators”.
The PBTL production complex is a
83
special case because the relations between producers and
users of technologies (i.e., the parties in the division of labor) are subject
to uncertainty that is greater than in the other cases and qualitatively
different. User-producer
transactions take many different forms: between capital goods producers and
their users in production of final outputs; between producers of components and
consumers of components; between producers of information and users of such
information; between producers of materials and consumers of such materials; and
between producers of final products and final market consumers. A given transactional relationship in the
presence of learning tends to be qualitatively more dense than in the case of
simple market fluctuations because it involves new and unstandardized knowledge.
In the case of user-producer
relations under conditions of technological change, the difficult and
not-easily-objectifiable process of interpretation of evidence and opportunities
is critical. Moreover, the whole
transactional structure may be subject to redefinition as new types of products
and new firms enter the structure and as whole new sub-nodes, channels, and
codes of transaction are defined. In other words, where rapid learning is
taking place, the transactional structure is likely to involve constant
negotiation, renegotiation, and dependence on achieved understandings as the
basis of achieving common reinterpretations of new evidence and opportunities.
This hypothesis applies not only to
incremental innovations, but to radical innovations as well,
as:
the codes developed to communicate a constant, or a
gradually changing technology will become inadequate. Established producers, following a given
technological trajectory, will have difficulties in evaluating the potentials of
the new paradigm. Users will have
difficulties in decoding the communications coming from producers, developing
new products, built according to the new paradigm. In this case, geographical
and cultural distance might play an even more important role than in the case of
incremental innovation. The lack of
standard criteria for sorting out what is the best paradigm, implies that
“subjective” elements in user-producer relationships ... will become important
(Lundvall 1990, 19).
In technologically dynamic production complexes, then,
there is a strong reason for the existence of regional clusters or
agglomerations.5 Agglomeration appears to be a principal
geographical form in which the trade-off between lock-in, technological
flexibility (and the search for quasi-rents), and cost-minimization can be most
effectively managed, because it facilitates efficient operation of a cooperative
production network. Agglomeration,
in these cases, is the result not simply of standard localization economies
(which are based on the notion of allocative efficiency in minimizing costs),
but of “Schumpeterian” efficiencies.
Learning and Regional Context: The Qualitative
Specificity of Externalities
Not all agglomerations, even those with a deep vertical
division of labor and external economies of scope, are technologically dynamic,
and the mere existence of a deep division of labor does not guarantee that a
PBTL network is in place. We must
look to other conditions, having to do with the qualitative nature of
interactions between agents, as keys to their technological
dynamism.
A voluminous literature has attempted to identify
factors supposedly leading to the creation and success of
localized,
5. Learning, flexibility, and agglomeration tend to be
interdependent, but an important qualification must be noted. There is nothing deterministic about the
geographical form of a cooperative production network. Depending on the nature of the
transaction and the history, institutional structure, and geographical
distribution of key actors in an economy, agglomeration may be more or less
pronounced.
84
innovative production networks. This literature has two main arguments.
On the one hand, it attempts to
identify sets of discrete factors that underpin the production complex:
universities, airports, a good quality of life, the existence of highly trained
workers, and so on. On the other
hand, it advances the concept of an “innovative milieu,” which in turn often is
based on the “synergies” of the factors. The problem is that the former
literature’s lists can be cut to fit any circumstance, and that no particular
factor or combination thereof corresponds to the cases. Moreover, it offers us no analytical way
to specify what is meant by “milieu” or “synergy.” An analytical alternative is
needed.
I argue that we must look at the codes, channels of
interaction, and ways of organizing and coordinating behaviors that make
learning possible. This is an
enormously complex theoretical problem, and I limit myself here to a few basic
points. If we assume an outer
technological frontier (maximum outer limit of existing fundamental or applied
knowledge) in a given industry, the question arises as to why some producers act
on it more than others, and why they act on it as they do. One obvious reason is that information is
imperfect, and some sets of producers have better institutions to reduce the
uncertainty associated with this information in such a way that they learn more
from it. But this is again just the
“weak” version of uncertainty. More
positively, the use and development of information so that technological
learning takes place has to do with the qualitative behaviors of agents in a
network.
Evidence suggests that not all agents are alike when it
comes to transactional activity. Economists such as Williamson assume that
all actors have universal behavioral principles, such as short-run maximizing
and opportunism (the “under-socialized” nature of homo economicu - Granovetter 1985). Implicitly, they consider different
organizational forms and transactions costs, holding the objects (products,
technologies) of economic activity constant so that the focus is on the optimal
arrangements between agents. Our
stress on product innovation suggests that these objects are not fixed: indeed,
that it is the simultaneous development of objects by agents (subjects) that
cuts to the heart of the economic development process (Boltanski and Thevenot
1987). Needs and the possibilities
for addressing them are defined simultaneously. This insight opens up a field of
investigation of economic organization that goes beyond the transactions costs
school in two ways.
First, under conditions of continuous, open-ended
product innovation or differentiation, institutional arrangements are the result
of this simultaneous subject-object interaction; there is no optimal arrangement
because what is to be optimized changes along with the institutional
arrangements themselves. Thus, as
the recent case study literature on PBTL networks suggests, production systems
develop products under different mixes of competition, cooperation, trust, and
opportunism of the transactors, and agents (firms, individuals) are motivated by
different values about what is good and bad, just and unjust, as well as
different localized incentive structures (Sabel 1990). These localized expectations figure
importantly in the agents’ short-term choices (time horizons, payoff points,
etc.; for a case study of trust relations in French subcontracting networks, see
Lorenz 1988). In one well-known
critique of standard transactional theory, these features of transactional
behavior were aptly described as the social “embeddedness” of economic activity
(Granovetter 1985). Here I have
gone beyond Granovetter’s critique to center on the definition of economic
objects themselves.
If the rationalities of producers and users - their
expectations, preference structures, and so on - differ considerably from place
to place, some types of rationality and the behavioral routines, rules, and
institutions that underlie them seem to be more effective than others
at
85
promoting interactions that lead to technological
learning. The potential positive
externalities of production networks are only realized according to the concrete
qualities of the transactions themselves. Our attention should, therefore, focus on
the theoretical and empirical problem of the qualitative basis and
differentiation of external economies of networks.
Second, agents (subjects) are produced by their
underlying environment. Such agents
are the most critical economic resource when considering PBTL. Identifying the structure of
participation of these agents in the production system is therefore necessary.
What brings agents into mutual
engagement in such a way that PBTL occurs? We can call such principles of mutual
engagement the conventions of that production network and its
agglomeration. Conventions lie
beneath the regularized social interactions that sometimes appear as formal
rules or institutions, and at other times appear simply as routines or unwritten
“rules of the game.” Conventions
describe the underlying forms of collective order of the production system,
especially the underlying principles of justification (and distribution) of
rewards to the various agents in the system.
Specifically, the conventional environment of PBTL
systems is likely to rest on rules and practices that: (1) coordinate shared
preferences, particularly with respect to growth or product quality; (2)
reconcile discordant preferences that the key actors are encouraged to
participate in innovative activity; and (3) regulate the buying and selling of
goods and services by defining standards of value (e.g., wage/effort bargains).
In all, we can say that the
analysis of conventions helps us understand why different kinds of resources
(skills, capital, etc.) are mobilized and bound together in a division of labor
and why the possibilities for doing this differ from place to
place.
A final dimension of the problem of learning, networks,
lock-in, and conventions is that many kinds of knowledge - once deployed in the
context of a specific learning system - are nonetheless not fully appropriable
by those who do the learning. Knowledge, whether in the form of
capital, products, or theoretical knowledge itself, leaks and is easily
imitated. Even a learning system
that is qualitatively distinctive and deeply rooted in specific local conditions
is viable only by virtue of its true dynamism, not by virtue of its particular
outputs in the short run. Yet
production networks and their institutionalized conventions and rationalities
are themselves subject to the same path dependency and lock-in that they are
designed to help individual firms avoid. As with any complex social system,
networks may have better or worse capacities for collective adjustment in the
face of external events and higher or lower levels of internal dynamism. Such capacities are essential when the
technological frontier (i.e., the basic menu of technological possibilities,
either within a sector or in the appearance of new product groups) changes in
the form of a cluster of basic, radical innovations:
The costs involved in breaking up existing codes and
channels of information will tend to cement the existing structure... The force
of resistance might be strongest where the interaction has been most effective
in establishing strong poles of competitiveness (Lundvall 1990,
21).
Thus we need to know not only what elements are
responsible for turning production networks into technologically dynamic
learning systems, and what specific conventions select these specialties for
each country, but also the mechanisms that make collective adjustments of the
learning systems possible or, in contrast, what sorts of conventions promote
collective lock-in or blockage of learning in networks (Lorenz
1991).
The Territorialization of Learning: Regions and
Countries
Social scientists have recently, rather belatedly, begun
to recognize that the
86
invention and modification of products and processes -
i.e., innovation and learning - rest on an extraordinarily complex variety of
institutions, social habits, ideologies, and expectations, and that even firm
and market structures are to a certain extent outcomes of these underlying
social structures. The habits of
production cannot be reduced to discrete “factors” such as quantity of R&D
expenditures, entrepreneurialism, the availability of capital, and so
on.
Most of this reflection has been inspired by the rise of
Japanese and German economic power and the growing recognition that these
countries (i.e., their firms, labor processes, institutions, and cultures)
really differ in fundamental ways from their less successful competitors. To date, however, the debate has been
posed almost exclusively in terms of the differences between “national
innovation systems.” Processes that
operate at the national level undoubtedly have much to do with the selection of
national specializations and the differential success levels of countries. I advance the further hypothesis that -
at least in some countries - political- economic cultures, rules, and
institutions are also highly differentiated at the regional
level.
One important dimension of such regionalization is the
production of public goods upon which technological learning depends, especially
in the form of skilled production and intellectual labor, where no single firm
or training institution can possibly produce these resources. The external economies that attach to the
training and specialization of such labor have to do not only with the
localization of training, but with the fact that interpersonal knowledge is a
key ingredient of the formation of each trained cohort of workers, with
cognitive and communicative elements that we are only beginning to analyze in
social scientific terms.
In any case, since countries are leading innovators in a
relatively few industries and these industries tend to be highly concentrated in
particular regions, inquiry at the level of industry and region incorporates
national-level forces while also permitting focused investigation of specific
regional processes, rules, habits, and institutions 6 This, then, is the field of inquiry into the sources of
PBTL systems, and the differences between these systems and others. It involves a structured
conceptualization of a broad set of features of a regional political-economic
culture, its institutions, and the behavioral routines of its collective
agents.
Table 2:
Top Fifty
Table 3:
Top Fifty Italian
Industries Ranked in Terms of World Export Share, 1985
Table 4:
Top Fifty French
Industries Ranked in Terms of World Export Share, 1985
Table 5A:
The Roots of
Export Specialization: PBTL vs. the Rest,
Table 5B:
The Roots of
Export Specialization: Learning/Economics of Variety vs. the Rest,
Table 5C:
The Roots of
Export Specialization: Learning/Economics of Variety vs. the Rest,
France
Table 5D:
Totals for Three
Countries
Table 6:
The Degree of
Country Specialization in HTO, DIC, and PMM Industries,
1985
Table 7:
Technological
Districts in the