The Competitiveness of Nations
in a Global Knowledge-Based Economy
H.H. Chartrand
April 2002
Ron Martin and
Peter Sunley
Paul Krugman’s Geographical
Economics and Its Implications for Regional Development Theory:
A Critical Assessment (cont'd)
Economic Geography
Volume 72, Issue 3
July 1996, pp. 259-292
Index
Abstract
Trade, Externalities, and Industrial Localization: The
Bases of Krugman’s “Geographical Economics”
The New Trade Theory and Location
Increasing Returns and Imperfect
Competition
The Role and Implications of
Externalities
Krugman’s Geographical Economics and Economic Geography:
A Critical Comparison
The Resurgence of Regional
Economies
The New Political Economy of Trade
Krugman’s Model of Economic Integration and Regional
Development: The Lessons of the
Economic Integration and Regional
Specialization
Economic Integration and Divergent Regional
Growth
Trade and the Regional Policy Issue
Geographical Clustering and Strategic Industrial
Policy
References
Trade and the Regional Policy Issue
Like much of his other work, Krugman’s views on the role
of trade and industrial policy have shifted over time. In his early writings he reacted against
the idea of targeted industrial policies, on the grounds that they were based on
crude misconceptions and that even if more-sophisticated theorizations could be
found such policies were still unlikely to be effective in practice (Krugman
1983, 1983b, 1984). Not long after,
however, he had constructed a sophisticated theoretical argument for “strategic
trade policy” (Krugman 1986). One
of the most contentious aspects of the new trade theory has been the debate it
has generated over the question of strategic industrial policy. Whereas conventional trade theory denies
there is any case for “activist” trade or industrial policies, the new trade
theory directly challenges the conventional view. According to Krugman (1986) and other new
trade theorists (for example, Brander and Spencer 1983, 1985), an “activist”
trade policy can benefit a country relative to free trade in two ways. The first is through “rent creation.”
If a government can promote a new
or expanded monopoly position for domestic factors of production in industries
that trade internationally, then a targeted industrial policy can in principle
raise a country’s income at foreign expense. Second, targeting can raise income if
there are certain industries in which the resources committed by individual
firms indirectly raise the earnings of other firms’ resources - that is, where
external economies can be generated. In both instances, the argument is that
it may well be possible to identify some “strategic sectors” that at the margin
are more valuable than others, and that the promotion of these sectors through
protection, export subsidies, support of R&D, and so on could raise national
income.
More recently, however, Krugman has reacted against
strategic trade policy. In
281
Peddling Prosperity (1994c), he questions the theoretical validity of
strategic industrial policy and goes on to berate leading American politicians
(especially President Clinton) and their economic advisors (especially Thurow
and Reich) for misappropriating strategic trade theory and applying it in a
“simple-minded way.” Both Reich
(1991) and Thurow (1994) are criticized for peddling the view that if the United
States is to compete in the global economy, the government should abandon its
notions of free trade and minimalist industrial intervention and instead pursue
a more activist stance aimed at promoting the shift of American industry into
“high value” (Reich) and “sunrise” (Thurow) sectors. Krugman believes that such views are
based on fallacious theory, impractical politics, and an erroneous obsession
with the idea of competitiveness”: “While competitive problems could arise in
principle, as a practical, empirical matter the major nations of the world are
not to any significant degree in economic competition with each other” (Krugman
1994a, 35). In his view,
competitiveness relies on the metaphor of a country being a big corporation,
when, in fact, countries (and regions) are nothing like corporations. Hence it is very difficult to establish a
meaningful definition of national or regional competitiveness. Furthermore, he argues that it is wrong
to see international trade as competition - as a sort of zero-sum game - when it
is a process of exchange involving mutual benefit. By the early 1990s, then, Krugman had
come to denounce strategic trade policy as “bad economics.” Yet, while Krugman has vigorously
attacked the whole ensemble of policies that have come to be labeled as
“strategic trade policy,” it appears that he now sees a role for a limited and
focused industrial policy.
Geographical Clustering and Strategic Industrial
Policy
In a recent paper Krugman (1993b, 160) states that he
has “now changed his mind and … gone, at least slightly, soft on industrial
policy.” His initial skepticism of
the theoretical credentials and practical applicability of the external
economies rationale for targeted industrial policies was on the grounds that
only technological, not pecuniary external economies are of concern, that
technological externalities in any case are of limited significance, and that
they are international rather than national in scope (Krugman 1983b, 1984).
But, as we have seen, he now
believes that external economies associated with market-size effects are
substantial and demonstrable (and often indistinguishable from technological
external economies), and this means that targeted industrial policies have a
potential role after all (Krugman 1987a, 1993b). Moreover,
many
of the important market-size effects apply not at the level of the international
or even the national economy, but at a regional or local level. The argument that the gains from support
of industries that generate external economies will be dissipated abroad is
therefore mostly wrong. (Krugman 1993b, 167)
In this revised view of industrial policy, not only are
regional and local industrial clusters considered to provide empirical proof of
the importance of external economies, such clusters help to define what
industries should be supported. Geographical clustering provides the
justification for industrial intervention, and the aim of that intervention
should be to foster local externalities. In effect, what Krugman seems to be
suggesting, though he does not use the term explicitly, is that the only
justifiable form of industrial (trade) policy is in fact regional industrial
development policy. In line with
strategic trade theory, the underlying premise is that national industrial
comparative advantage can be created through supportive and targeted industrial
policies which aim to create and facilitate key sectoral specializations. The twist in Krugman’s argument, however,
is that the most effective scale at which to create that advantage is at the
level of regional clusters. Essentially the same argument
is
282
implicit in Porter’s (1990) major work on national
competitive advantage. Indeed, he
now sees local and economic development policies as having an instrumental role
in fostering national industrial competitiveness (Porter
1994).
It is only a small step from this to argue that the
promotion of specialized export clusters is also the most viable approach to
reviving and regenerating old industrial regions. This is, in fact, what certain writers on
flexible specialization and industrial districts have implied. These authors use the success of certain
well-known specialized (usually export-orientated) industrial districts as a
model for “indigenous” local economic regeneration more generally (see, for
example, Hirst and Zeitlin 1989; Pyke, Becattini, and Sengenberger 1989; Sabel
1989; Stohr 1989; Cooke 1990; Scott 1992b). The path to the reindustrialization of
economically and structurally depressed regions is seen to be via the promotion
and support of neo-Marshallian small-firm, flexibly specialized production
complexes involving dense local networks of cooperation, competition, and
horizontal interdependencies. In
some ways this support for a local industrial strategy based on multiple
externalities is similar to Krugman’s rationale for industrial policy. However, the advocacy of regional export
specialization either as a local economic development strategy or as a form of
trade policy is contentious.
The key question over the promotion of regional
industrial specialization is whether the potential advantages are outweighed by
the likelihood of greater regional instability and shocks, and the risk of
structural depression. As Krugman
(1993d) notes for the case of Massachusetts, regional industrial specialization
is a double-edged sword: it can be the basis of a high rate of export-led local
economic growth in one period, but the source of prolonged local economic
depression if that demand subsequently collapses or is captured by other
competing regions (often in other countries). This is precisely what happened to many
of the specialized industrial districts celebrated by Alfred Marshall early this
century (for example, see Sunley 1992). An equally persuasive case can be made
that industrial diversification rather than specialization is the most
appropriate regional development policy route, that diversifying the regional
industrial “portfolio” reduces the susceptibility of the regional economy to
adverse demand shocks and localized structural crisis (this is the general
conclusion of the portfolio studies referred to earlier; see also Geroski
1989).
Krugman, on the other hand, appears to believe that the
most important policy response to the possibility of regional instability in
more-specialized regions is fiscal stabilization. In the case of European economic
integration, for example, Krugman suggests that national budgets will have to be
substantially centralized so that automatic federal European fiscal transfers
can perform the required stabilization role when asymmetric regional shocks
occur. 23 He notes the way in which the
While the US does not cope with the problems perfectly
(as the current travails not only of New England but of the North East, in
general, and increasingly of California, demonstrate), a highly federalized
fiscal system helps a good deal. The lack of such a system in
23. In the
European case, although fiscal federalism is indeed a natural corollary to EMU,
national governments in a future European monetary union would not lose all of
their instruments of economic policy. National budgetary policies would
continue to have some, even if constrained, automatic stabilizing role (see
Boonstra (1991) on the limits that EMU will impose on national budgetary
autonomy). In this sense member
states in a European EMU would be somewhat different from the individual states
in the
283
Krugman is at pains to distinguish this form of regional
policy response from that needed to ameliorate “core-periphery” patterns of
uneven regional development or the regional decline that stems from
specialization in outmoded industries and products. The policy response to these sorts of
regional issues, he says, “is much less related to EMU than the stabilization
problem” (Krugman 1993d, 259).
However, while automatic fiscal transfers may well help
to alleviate and stabilize the income and growth problems associated with
economically depressed regions, they are not an adequate response to uneven
regional development. By
themselves, they are not sufficient to recast the structure and dynamics of
regional development so as to improve the long-term economic performance and
wealth of the regions concerned. This is why, of course, historically many
European countries have developed elaborate systems of region-specific
developmental aid and assistance, and why the European Union has been
strengthening and reforming its own centrally administered regional structural
funds in the context of the movement toward increasing economic integration (and
enlargement) of the Union (see, for example, Martin 1993; Collier 1994). Krugman’s distinction between regional
instabilities due to idiosyncratic demand shocks and regional problems of a more
“core-periphery” and “structural” nature is surprising and questionable. For if, as he argues, short-term regional
shocks have long-term effects on regional growth, then interregional fiscal
stabilization is an inadequate policy response, and other, more strategic forms
of regional policy are required.
In our view, the proposal of fiscal federalism does not
temper the worry that regional clusters of specialized industry will be unstable
and fragile. The basic tension in
Krugman’s argument remains - namely, how to reconcile his suggestion that the
aim of industrial policy should be to promote industrially specialized regional
clusters with his thesis that increased regional industrial concentration and
specialization leads to regional economic instability and divergent long-term
growth paths. The response of the
new industrial geography to this dilemma, of course, is to insist that flexibly
specialized industrial districts are more adaptable to economic and
technological change by virtue of the dynamism and networking of the small
enterprises of which they are (invariably assumed to be) composed. However, this claim remains far from
proven. In addition, the number of
flexibly specialized districts remains small, and their origins and dynamics are
matters of debate (see Markusen 1993; Markusen and Park 1993). This is not to dismiss the new
“indigenous” approach to regional policy based on arguments of (flexibly)
specialized industrial development; but it is to signal that this approach is no
more of a general panacea for uneven regional development than was the old model
of redistributive regional policy. Nor do we wish to imply that increasing
returns and external economies are unimportant in the regional policy debate.
To the contrary, not only is there
evidence from Europe that increasing returns industries are more concentrated in
regions with better infrastructures, especially technological and educational
infrastructures (Martin and Rogers 1994a, 1994b), endogenous growth theory also
suggests that external economies and technological spillovers are likely to play
a key role in the local growth process in an integrated Europe. But in our judgment, there is an urgent
need for much more thought on how local and regional policies can foster and
support these externalities without simultaneously narrowing the industrial base
and increasing the vulnerability of regions to demand
shocks.
A few years ago, Neil Smith (1989) argued for a
rebuilding of regional theory within geography based on a synthesis of ideas
from location theory and uneven development theory. More recently, Krugman (1993a) has argued
for a similar
284
synthesis of location theory and trade theory, for using
economic geography as a key component in the construction of a new “geographical
economics” of trade. In this paper
we have sought to provide a critical assessment of Krugman’s ideas on economic
geography and his attempts to use these ideas to forge a “geographical
economics.” Because of the enormous
volume and breadth of his writings we have had to skate across many of his
ideas, and as a result we have no doubt failed to accord some of them the full
attention they deserve. In
addition, Krugman’s tendency to constantly revise and even reject his earlier
ideas renders the task of assessment akin to tracking a moving target. Nevertheless, we believe we have
succeeded in isolating the core components of his arguments sufficiently to be
able to identify some of their main strengths and weaknesses, particularly as
they relate to the question of regional growth and development. In many ways, Krugman’s approach to
economic geography is a regional science one, a reworking of traditional
location theory concepts and models. The new economic and industrial
geography, of course, has moved well away from that tradition. For this reason, it might well be
questioned whether Krugman’s work contains anything that is new or useful for
economic geographers. It would be
wrong to be so readily dismissive, however; Krugman’s work is not as simplistic
as
One strength of Krugman’s work, without doubt, is that
his linking of external economies and regional industrial agglomeration with
trade provides an important corrective to the flexible specialization thesis of
the new industrial geography, in which regional industrial development is viewed
overwhelmingly as an indigenous process and the role of trade is typically
either subordinated or neglected altogether. Furthermore, Krugman’s emphasis on
imperfect competition and pecuniary externalities likewise exposes the
limitations of the conceptions of externalities now prevalent within the
geographical literature. The thrust
of flexible specialization ideas in economic geography is that agglomeration is
associated with the shift from vertical integration to the horizontal
integration of related activities among small, competitive firms which cluster
together to minimize transaction costs. Williamsonian transaction costs economics
- itself a neoclassical-oriented form of institutional economics - has been used to give a new theoretical
underpinning to
285
transforming the space economy, and hence to some extent
holds some important lessons for Krugman’s analysis in this respect, it too has
yet to explore fully the cumulative and spillover effects associated with
technological change.
A second significant aspect of Krugman’s geographical is
the recognition that regional economic development is a historical,
path-dependent process. His
repeated exhortation that “history matters,” both in terms of the arbitrary
initial conditions and accidental events that set in motion particular patterns
of industrial development over time and space and in terms of the subsequent
“locking in” of those patterns via self-reinforcing effects, is not of course
particularly novel to economic geographers. Geographers have long recognized that a
given pattern of uneven regional development, once established, tends to exhibit
a high degree of persistence or ‘inertia” over time, and that this inertia can
operate either to foster regional growth or to retard it. The more recent interest by geographers
in the local socio-institutional “embedded-ness” of economic activity also bears
upon the issues of path dependence and lock-in. In Krugman’s view the role played by
geography in determining “lock-in” is strictly an increasing returns phenomenon,
in the form of the Marshallian externalities associated with local industrial
agglomeration (or, under certain circumstances, in the form of self-fulfilling
expectations). What he fails to
consider is the influence exerted by local institutional, social, and cultural
structures in facilitating or constraining local economic development. This neglect would seem to stem in large
part from Krugman’s complaint that noneconomic or “social” factors are not
easily modeled and that they should therefore be left to sociologists. But as recent studies in the new
industrial and economic geography have begun to show, the “thickness” and nature
of such socio-institutional “externalities” are fundamental to the initial
emergence, trajectory, and adaptability of industrial districts and regional
economies. Thus Krugman is right to
stress the role of geography in the historical, path-dependent nature of the
economic process, but he fails to explicate the nature of that
role.
A third aspect of Krugman’s geographical economics that
we want to highlight, and which also has both strengths and weaknesses, is his
analysis of the way that region-specific shocks can have long-term growth
consequences. How regions respond
and adjust to demand and supply shocks, both in the short term and in the long
run, in an increasingly deregulated, market-propelled, and uncertain world is an
important research issue, but one that has been neglected by the new industrial
geography. Krugman’s analysis for
the EU regions, using the
There is, then, considerable scope for a potentially
fruitful cross-fertilization of ideas between Krugman’s geographical economics
and the new industrial-economic geography, and for the elaboration of each.
Both draw heavily on a
Marshal-
286
lian
view of industrial localization. But whereas the new industrial geography
has sought to reinterpret the Marshallian account in terms of transaction cost
economics, Krugman instead has tried to link Marshallian industrial localization
with the economics of imperfect competition, increasing returns, path
dependence, and cumulative causation. These concerns were at the center of
Nicholas Kaldor’s (1978, 1981, 1985) earlier seminal work on trade, endogenous
growth, and regional development, a debt that Krugman
acknowledges:
This clear dependence on history is the most convincing
evidence available that we live in an economy closer to Kaldor’s vision of a
dynamic world driven by cumulative processes than to the standard constant
returns model. (1991a, 9-10)
Krugman even goes so far as to admit that in a sense his
own work is only “a repetition” of Kaldor’s ideas. There are significant differences between
the two, however. In his quest for
economic rigor, Krugman’s mathematical formalization of the processes of
industrial agglomeration and uneven regional development has taken him away from
the richness of Kaldor’s original approach toward the limited abstract
landscapes of regional science. Indeed, in Development, Geography and
Economic Theory (Krugman 1995) and The Self-Organising Economy
(1996), his role model seems to be that doyen of regional science Walter
Isard, rather than Nicholas Kaldor, who, one suspects, would have been extremely
skeptical of the unrealistic, deductive model-building that is the hallmark of
the regional science tradition. And
despite Krugman’s apparent agreement with Kaldor’s argument for the “irrelevance
of equilibrium economics,” the ghosts of constrained maximization and
equilibrium solutions still haunt much of his analysis. 24
There would be much to be gained, in our view, if both
Krugman’s geographical economics and the new industrial and economic geography
revisited the method and the message of Kaldor’s work. But that, as Krugman would say, is
another story.
24. The same is true of the new trade theory and the new
endogenous growth theory more generally. Many of the ideas found in these theories
were in fact anticipated by Kaldor.
But whereas he eschewed the deductive and mathematical for the inductive
and realistic (as expressed in his emphasis on “stylized facts” and
nonequilibrium), the new theorists have deliberately sought to “systematize” his
ideas through mathematical formalism and appeal to all-embracing principles of
optimizing economic behavior (see the assessments by Kitson and Michie 1995;
Skott and Auerbach 1995).