The Competitiveness of Nations
in a Global Knowledge-Based Economy
H.H. Chartrand
April 2002
Ron Martin and Peter Sunley
Paul Krugman’s Geographical
Economics and Its Implications for Regional Development Theory:
A Critical Assessment (cont'd)
Economic Geography
Volume 72, Issue 3
July 1996, pp. 259-292
Index
Abstract
Trade, Externalities, and Industrial Localization: The
Bases of Krugman’s “Geographical Economics”
The New Trade Theory and Location
Increasing Returns and Imperfect
Competition
The Role and Implications of
Externalities
Krugman’s Geographical Economics and Economic Geography:
A Critical Comparison
The Resurgence of Regional
Economies
The New Political Economy of Trade
Economic Integration and Regional
Specialization
Economic Integration and Divergent Regional
Growth
Trade and the Regional Policy Issue
Strategic Trade Policy
Geographical Clustering and Strategic Industrial
Policy
Conclusions
References
Krugman’s Geographical Economics and Economic Geography:
A Critical Comparison
Clearly, Krugman shares an interest in regional
agglomeration and the geographical consequences of trade with many economic
geographers. At the same time, his
treatment of these issues has been significantly different from the approaches
pursued in economic geography in recent years. In this part of the paper we shall
examine the most important of these differences and consider the lessons that
Krugman and economic geographers can learn from each other. As we have noted already, a fundamental
difference between Krugman’s geographical economics and the various schools of
contemporary economic geography is one of method. Krugman’s reliance on formal models means
that his work is rigorous and supported by mathematical proofs. In his view, the dependence of many of
these models on unrealistic assumptions is not a grave problem nor a serious
limitation. Instead, he appears to
regard these models as rough metaphors or representations of the core of real
world problems (Krugman 1995). When
the models’ results are found to be inadequate, their assumptions can be
modified. In contrast, most
contemporary economic geography has abandoned the use of formal modeling and is
dominated instead by various types of political economy, which aim, above all,
to be “realistic.” From this
perspective, Krugman’s models have an inadequate sense of geographical and
historical context. Knox and Agnew
(1994), for example, argue that Krugman’s core-periphery model in Geography
and Trade differs from other location models in that it does not suggest a
long-term process of conver
268
gence. Instead, “the long term never arrives”
(Knox and Agnew 1994, 83). There
are multiple equilibria as concentrations persist for long periods of time but
may then be unraveled by new patterns of concentration. However, Knox and Agnew insist
that
concentration somewhere . . . is the perpetual rule.
So though apparently attentive to
historical change, this model is static in its assumptions about the operation
of economic-locational principles. The same principles of increasing
returns, imperfect competition, and agglomeration are at work in the same way
all the time. From this point
of view, geographical outcomes can change but the process driving them does not.
(1994, 83; original emphasis)
While this phrasing may be too strong,
12
Krugman (1991a) clearly states that the patterns of concentration that he
describes are typical only of some industries under certain conditions;
nevertheless, it does identify an important weakness in Krugman’s work. He claims that the same broad locational
forces which explain the growth of nineteenth-century concentrations also
underlie the continued tendency to agglomeration. Indeed, this is one reason why he is
reluctant to emphasize technological spillovers as a key determinant of
contemporary clusters. At the same
time, however, Krugman makes several passing references to the way in which the
nature of agglomeration has changed over time. Thus he suggests, in one paper, that the
railway ad steamship were responsible for the emergence of core-periphery
distinctions and that the age of this type of divergence may have passed. but
such a “throw-away” suggestion requires a great deal more explanation. The historical grounding of Krugman’s
approach remains unclear and clouded by ambiguity. What is clear is that his emphasis on
continuity in the forces responsible for capital’s agglomeration contrasts with
economic geographers’ focus on historical patterns of restructuring. However, the relative merits of this more
historical approach depend on precisely how change is theorized and
explained. It is impossible here to
talk about economic geography as a whole; we have therefore selected two
relevant areas of work, namely the recent literature in industrial geography on
regional agglomeration and recent writing on theorizing the geography of
trade.13
The Resurgence of Regional
Economies
During the past decade, the most influential approach to
industrial organization within economic geography has been the notion of a
fundamental transition from Fordist mass production to more flexible production
methods, such as flexible specialization. Scott and Storper (1992a, 1992b), Scott
(1988), Storper and
12. After all, most of the main schools of economic
geography and political economy may be criticized on similar grounds. All, for example, assume that the basic
laws of economic development (as they perceive them) remain essentially
unchanged as capitalism evolves over historical time.
13. These are two of the leading fields in contemporary
(post- Marxist) economic geography. It would require another paper to
consider Krugman’s work in relation to the complete corpus of geographical work
on uneven regional development.
269
costs
and wider opportunities for matching needs and capabilities” (Scott and Storper
1992b, 13). In summary, the shift
to flexible specialization has been responsible for the rise of new industrial
districts and for the new, or renewed, significance of regional agglomeration
(Sabel 1989). While there are many
contrasts between this “new industrial geography” and Krugman’s geographical
economics (see Table 1), we shall focus on three issues: the treatment of
industrial and market structure, of externalities, and of nonmarket transactions
and relations.
As we have seen, Krugman tends to rely on several
abstract models of monopolistic and oligopolistic market structure. The assumptions of these models are in
some ways unrealistic, but the underlying rationale is that they are useful
because of the pervasive presence of imperfect competition. In contrast, the flexible specialization
approach has envisaged a new type of competition involving downsizing and
disintegration and therefore a movement back toward perfect competition. However, the idea that corporate
disintegration is a necessary response to uncertainty can be criticized (see,
for example, Lovering 1990; Phelps 1992). Moreover, as Phelps (1992) has argued,
Scott’s analysis of the causes of agglomeration pertains primarily to situations
approximating to that of perfect competition. In Phelps’s view, “The assumption of
near-perfect competition is otherwise implicit in an analysis which applies to
single plant firms and neglects considerations of differential economic power
embodied in linkage structures” (1992, 41). This is especially problematic when the
analysis is applied to international trade. As Markusen (1993, 287) writes, “Most
important internationally traded industries are now multinucleated, with large
national firms thrust into more spirited competition with similarly sized and
politically well-endowed firms from other nations.” Hence, “the number of players is
relatively small, their sizes and clout are varied, and none of them
is
Table 1
A Comparison of Krugman’s “Geographical Economics” with the “New
Industrial Geography”
270
unaware of the behaviour of its neighbors. These are characteristics of oligopolized
markets, not perfectly competitive ones.”
Several arguments have been used to support the
association of near-perfect competition with agglomeration. One is the finding that in some
industries and places larger producers are located away from local clusters of
industry (Hoare 1975; Scott 1986), and another is the observation that the
decline of some industrial districts has been associated with the concentration
of production into larger firms (Steed 1971). These are contingent findings,
however. For example, Scott (1992a)
notes that large producers are integral to the Southern Californian computer
districts. Even where large firms
are not found in local industrial clusters, they may be central to the regional
and metropolitan concentrations modeled by Krugman. It cannot be assumed that internal
economies of scale and scope act against agglomeration. Indeed, the intraindustry trade
literature implies that, with increasing product diversity, internal economies
and agglomeration become more closely linked. There is clearly a need to research the
relations between market structure and locational dynamics in more
detail.
This difference on the issue of competition has
important consequences for understanding externalities. In order to compare Krugman’s
representation of externalities with that used in the “new industrial
geography,” it is helpful to set both approaches within a general framework.
De Melo and Robinson (1990) argue
that three main approaches to externalities are apparent in recent economic
literature. The first is the
Marshallian externalities approach, which we discussed above. They suggest that some parts of
endogenous growth theory fall within this approach. For example, in an article on the
externalities arising from human capital formation, Lucas (1988) talked about
increasing returns at an economy wide level. The second type of externality that De
Melo and Robinson identify are those that result in uneven rates of growth and
occur with imperfect competition. Again, there are examples from endogenous
growth theory: Romer (1990) sees investment in R&D in a situation of
monopolistic competition as generating externalities in disembodied
knowledge. The third type of
externality arises from demand spillovers between sectors and industries. Murphy, Schleifer, and Vishny (1989), for
example, argue that there are low-level equilibrium traps, where
industrialization remains unprofitable. Industrial production only becomes
profitable for individual firms in the context of more general demand
linkages.
This framework provides a means of comparing the two
approaches to agglomeration (Table 2). Krugman’s focus on market-size effects is
clearly closest to, and draws most heavily on, pecuniary externalities.
14 As we have
seen, his explanation of local clustering also invokes certain types of
Marshallian external economy. Importantly, he has tended to downplay
the significance of externalities based on spillovers in technological
knowledge. Krugman (1987c)
describes these as “elusive,” preferring to concentrate on externalities that
can be modeled. The difference
between his approach and that of the “new industrial geography” is apparent.
In accordance with the reliance on
situations of near-perfect competition, Marshallian external economies have been
at the forefront of the industrial districts literature. As Phelps has argued, and as Krugman’s
account demonstrates, the external economies that can be used in this approach
are only a subset of the range available (Phelps 1992). To a certain extent this limitation has
been weakened by those revisionist studies of industrial
14. Krugman (1993b, 1995) describes this type of
external economy as similar to those envisaged in “Big Push” interpretations of
industrialization. He argues that a
large-scale program of industrialization can take advantage of external
economies and complementarities and so reduce the risk of investment (see
Rosenstein-Rodan 1943).
271
Table 2
districts which argue that large producers can imitate
decentralization. However, the
contradiction between a commitment to perfect competition and the dependence of
Schumpeterian models of “creative destruction” and local technological
spillovers on imperfect competition cannot be resolved easily. 15
The differences between Krugman’s geographical economics
and the recent work in economic geography on regional development are not
confined to industrial structure and externalities, but also extend to the
question of nonmarket transactions. Thus another important contrast between
Krugman’s approach and those of economic geographers is the manner in which the
increasing power of larger producers has been related to contemporary
localizations of industry. In
economic geography there has been some dissatisfaction with the way in which the
flexible specialization literature has ignored the increasing
internationalization of firm structures and globalization more generally (Amin
and Robins 1990; Gertler 1992). Consequently, there has been an interest
in the way in which large firms interact with industrial districts. In contrast to Krugman’s market-size
effects, however, the main emphasis has been on the intermingling of firm and
local networks (Amin and Thrift 1992; Grabher 1993). Networks have usually been defined as
types of organizational relation that are neither market transactions nor
hierarchies, and the term has been used to refer to cooperative and mutually
beneficial relationships among producers (Cooke and Morgan 1993). Using this definition, the boundaries of
firms become blurred, and firms and districts become intermingled. On the one hand,
15. Schumpeterian models of “creative destruction,”
technological spillovers, and endogenous growth depend on imperfect
competition. Typically, the
incentive for firms to develop new products and processes stems from the
temporary monopoly profits which they can earn (Grossman and Helpman 1991;
Aghion and Howitt 1993). This sits
uneasily with the new industrial geography’s emphasis on near-perfect
competition.
272
Krugman’s contrary emphasis on pecuniary relations is a
reminder to geographers not to lose sight of market effects. But on the other hand, Krugman’s neglect
of externalities that are intangible and leave no paper trail appears too
restrictive. As Jaffe, Trajtenberg,
and Henderson (1993) have pointed out, knowledge flows do sometimes leave a
paper trail, in the form of citation of patents.
The interest in network forms of organization in
economic geography reflects a more general concern to examine the ways in which
economic activities are “embedded” in, and made possible by, social and cultural
conditions. This has been applied
with particular force by Storper (1992a) to high-technology districts. As
The New Political Economy of
Trade
Recent years have seen a growing interest by economic
geographers in the spatial patterns of international trade. While this work has lacked a
comprehensive theoretical framework, it has nevertheless been characterized by
shared themes revolving around the inability of conventional geographies, based
on Ricardian comparative advantage, to explain fully the complex character of
contemporary international patterns. In accord with the “new trade theory,”
this geographical revival has stressed the importance of shifts in the world
economy and the rise of intraindustry and intracorporate trade. One of the defining features of this
revival has been a call to study the ways in which the geography of trade is
shaped by states and by trade regimes. This emphasis on state policy, and the
interpretation of trade on which it is based, contrasts with Krugman’s approach
in ways that raise fundamental questions about the effects of trade and its
policy implications.
Some years ago,
16. Amin and Thrift (1994) describe this embedding as
best summed up by the phrase “institutional thickness.” This is defined by a strong institutional
presence in a local area, high levels of interaction among these institutions,
strong social structures, and a collective awareness of common
enterprise.
273
plea
for an enlarged research agenda has begun to be recognized. Grant summarizes recent developments as
follows:
The
unifying theme in newer approaches is their study of the interactions between
governments and firms and their connections to trade and industrial policy
within the context of a politically and economically competitive world economy,
one in which governments attempt to “create” the most advantageous environment
for national business. Accordingly,
approaches recontextualize comparative advantage to include an understanding of
developments in the trade-industrial policy arena, (1994,
301)
In
line with this theme, Grant focuses on the role of governments, especially the
formation of regional blocs, and the role of firms as the bases of a more
comprehensive theory. Moreover, he
argues that high-technology trade occupies a key place in any new theory, as
success in high-technology bestows national benefits on productivity and
high-wage job creation (see also Drache and Gertler 1991). Likewise, in their recent study of trade
in textiles and clothing, Glasmeier, Thompson, and Kays (1993) contend that it
is necessary to understand how the actions of the state influence the structure
of global competition. Indeed, they
conclude that state actions have superseded market forces as the regulator of
the industry’s geographical evolution.
The conceptual movement away from orthodox comparative
advantage explanations has been most fully spelled out in Trading Industries,
Trading Regions, edited by Noponen, Graham, and Markusen (1993). Here again it is argued that success in
trade is fundamentally shaped by government intervention. In a chapter in that volume, Howes and
Markusen claim that governments have played a key role in creating and
maintaining industrial leadership, and that “in a world with governments’
successfully conducting such industrial and trade policies, open economies
without such efforts will find themselves the targets of import penetration and
potential export market shrinkage” Howes and Markusen 1993, 4). In this view, factor endowments can be
used to explain trade in minerals, agricultural goods, and some labor-intensive
consumer goods, but the majority of trade between developed market economies can
only be explained by a “dynamic revisionist” theory. This has four major tenets that
contradict orthodox trade theory. First, the mix of sectors matters, as
some industries have greater growth and productivity differentials. Second, growth is not constrained by
factors but by demand for the product. Third, in some industries rapid growth
leads to continuing success due to increasing returns. Fourth, because of the existence of
increasing returns, comparative advantage may conceivably be created by
strategic intervention on the part of nation-states and regional authorities.
On this basis they argue that the
orthodox view that free trade means growth for all regions is mistaken; instead,
“there is some danger that the unfettered pursuit of free trade will actually
depress wages and employment and lower world living standards” (Howes and
Markusen 1993, 35). Furthermore,
Markusen (1993) argues that in the
While this “dynamic revisionist” theory shares an
emphasis on “new trade theory” with Krugman, it more closely resembles the
strategic trade views of authors such as Tyson (1992) and Reich (1991), whom
Krugman (1994a, 1994c) has recently criticized. 17 As we have noted, Krugman remains convinced that the
mutual benefits of greater international trade outweigh the costs. Moreover, in his opinion, comparative
advantage is not just a sector-specific theory, it remains a general principle
that explains the beneficial
17. For a debate on Krugman’s critique see the
discussion on “The Fight over Competitiveness” in Foreign Affairs
(1994a), Friedman (1994), and The Economist (“The Economics of
Meaning” 1994).
275
consequences of trade. The concept makes clear that absolute
productivity advantage in some areas is not necessary for a country to gain from
economic integration. Trade,
therefore, is not a zero-sum game, so that concerns about national
competitiveness are misplaced and unfounded. Krugman (1987b) concedes that the
intellectual case for free trade has been weakened and that it is not an
absolute ideal, but he believes that it is still the best general policy or rule
of thumb. But Krugrnan’s position
faces several key questions. The
first is the extent to which this continuing use of comparative advantage is
compatible with his own emphasis on the pervasive presence of increasing
returns. Kaldor (1985), for
example, argues that the presence of increasing and diminishing returns
conflicts with the basic tenets of Ricardian comparative advantage. Simply put, he contends that diminishing
returns may mean that the resources released by trade will not necessarily be
employed in other sectors, so that there is a real possibility of absolute loss
(a “negative sum” game).
Conversely, increasing returns in some industries may inhibit the
transfer of resources elsewhere. Krugman’s economic geography pays
insufficient attention to these problems. This is reflected by his insistence that
it is pointless to try to identify high-return sectors, so that the mix of
sectors does not really matter. 18 Given his insistence on the importance of productivity,
it is surprising that he devotes little attention to the extent to which
high-technology sectors do generate the productivity spill-overs which some
authors have suggested (for example, Hanink 1994).
The second question is whether Krugman underestimates
the significance of adjustment costs and the obstacles to regional adjustment.
On the one hand, Krugman is
committed to a nonequilibrium view of economic geography in which there is no
process of convergence to a spatial equilibrium where all factors are equally
rewarded. He rejects the
neoclassical faith in the efficiency of markets on the grounds that the
collective result of individual choices may be to “lock-in” a bad result. On the other hand, in a methodological
sense, Krugman (1993a) insists that all economic models should contain a
well-specified equilibrium. By this
he means that they should specify how individuals behave and show how market
outcomes emerge from the interaction of these individual behaviors (Krugman
1993a, 115-16). He holds these two
opposing convictions together, it seems, through a commitment to a “new
Keynesian” brand of economics. According to this, economic trends and
patterns are the products of innumerable individual decisions, but these
decisions are not perfectly rational and informed. Instead they are frequently both
near-rational and individually reasonable and sensible. However, in imperfectly competitive
markets the aggregate result will be unstable and irrational. In his words, “What look like highly
irrational outcomes in the marketplace are caused by the interaction between
imperfectly competitive markets and slightly less than perfectly rational
individuals” (Krugman 1994c, 213). But if emphasis is placed on the second
of these factors, then the position is readily reassimilated into a neoclassical
view of the economy. It lends
itself to the view that markets would adapt efficiently and rapidly if only
people would behave rationally. This is exemplified, perhaps, by
Krugman’s (1993e) argument that Eurosclersosis, or the problem of a persistently
high level of unemployment in
18 Krugman’s (1994c) argument is that it is wrong to
assume that high-technology sectors such as computers and aerospace are the
sectors with highest value added per worker. In fact, he notes that in the
275
question of adjustment to the effects of trade is one
that Krugman has recently considered explicitly in terms of the impact of
economic integration on regional development, particularly in the European
Union, and it is to this aspect of his work that we now
turn.
Krugman’s Model of Economic Integration and Regional
Development:
The Lessons of the
The regional consequences of European economic
integration is an issue that has attracted surprisingly little attention from
economic geographers. At the heart
of this issue is the question of what the impact of progressive economic and
monetary integration in the European Union (EU) will be on regional patterns of
economic growth, employment, and income across member states. Economists have offered two opposing
answers to this question. On the
one hand, there are those who believe that the free movement of goods, services,
and capital associated with European economic and monetary integration (EMU)
should lead to regional convergence, not only in factor returns and economic
performance but also in economic structure. To the extent that wages and other costs
are lower in the less productive and slower-growing regions, the removal of
barriers to trade and factor movements, it is argued, should enable industries
and services in these regions to better exercise this comparative advantage and
to attract increased flows of capital investment. 19 This optimistic scenario is, on
balance, the view taken by the European Commission (Commission of the European
Communities 1991, 1994). In
contrast, others argue that economic integration will, intensify rather than
reduce regional imbalances in growth and income across the European Union. Instead of leading to equalizing
centrifugal movements of firms and investment toward depressed and peripheral
regions within the European Union, economic integration is likely to stimulate a
spatial reconfiguration of economic activity in favor of growth regions
precisely because these are the areas that already enjoy greater comparative
advantage in terms of access to markets, inputs, expertise, and business
infrastructure. 20
Krugman falls into the second of these two camps,
although he appears to subscribe to two somewhat different models of regional
divergence. In an earlier paper
(Krugman and Venables 1990), he follows a core-periphery argument not unlike
that in Geography and Trade. Although the removal of barriers to
trade and movement of capital and labor within the European Union will increase
the inflow of capital into, and the relative competitiveness of, the low-wage
peripheral regions, given transport costs this centrifugal process is on balance
likely to be outweighed by further concentration of industry and employment in
the high-wage core regions, because these areas have the largest markets,
well-developed external economies and infrastructures, and a comparative
advantage in terms of
19. Additionally, economic integration represents a
major supply shock to such regions, since it exposes them to the full force of
competition elsewhere in the system.
Such shocks, the argument continues, should (allowing for adjustment
lags) eliminate inefficient firms, work practices, and products in depressed
regions and improve their supply-side competitiveness and
flexibility.
20. Because the gains foreseen from completion of the
internal market are thought to be generated mainly endogenously, the various
processes of resource allocation are bound to cumulate resources in the leading
core regions. It is the
historically established competitive advantage of the growth regions which
enables them to capture a disproportionate share of the benefits of economic
integration. As for the depressed
and lagging regions, economic integration is seen as bringing prolonged problems
of adjustment and the need for greater levels of spending on regional
policies.
276
relative accessibility. His second approach is more emphatic, but
different in its specific arguments. In his paper on the “Lessons of
Massachusetts for EMU,” he supports the movement toward European economic
integration as “a generally good thing,” but argues that it will lead to greater
regional instability and divergence of regional growth rates (Krugman 1993d,
241). In developing this thesis he
begins by drawing on his earlier ideas on trade and the localization of
industries that we have discussed above:
For regional issues … in the EC, … the key aspect of
regional specialisation is the dependence of regional economies on export
clusters held together by Marshallian external economies … Are such regional
clusters more likely to form in a more integrated economy? The answer is definitely yes. (Krugman
1993d, 244)
These ideas are then used in a somewhat different way
from his earlier work to produce a theoretical account that not only carries
over some of the problems we have already highlighted, but also introduces
additional elements of contention.
The gist of this second model may be summarized as
follows. First, given the existence
of increasing returns, the expansion of interregional trade that EMU will bring
about will lead to greater regional industrial concentration and specialization
along essentially arbitrary lines. Once under way, there will be a tendency
for this regional specialization process to become “locked in” by the operation
of location-specific external economies. Second, Krugman argues that this
increased regional specialization will render the European regions much more
subject to random, idiosyncratic demand and technology shocks, so that
region-specific recessions and crises will be more likely to occur.
21 Third, when combined with the increased factor mobility
that integration will promote, such region-specific shocks will lead to
divergent long-term regional growth paths. Thus, fourth, given that under EMU member
states will no longer be able to use the exchange rate mechanism as a policy
instrument (see also Krugman 1989), the only way regional adjustment problems
can be ameliorated is by transferring a significant part of national budgets to
the European Union to allow fiscal federalism to function as an automatic
stabilizer.
Thus, in contrast to his previous work - for example, in
Geography and Trade (1991a) and Krugman and Venables (1990) - Krugman
argues that the process of uneven regional development that EMU may be expected
to produce will not be one of cumulative divergence into a core-periphery
pattern. He believes that the
forces generating this form of uneven regional development have probably reached
their limit in advanced industrial nations; indeed, he suggests that in both the
Another distinctive feature of Krugman’s exposition is
the method he uses to support his theory empirically. The
21 In an earlier paper, Krugman (1989) stressed that
increasing interdependence in
277
Using
simple measures of the dispersion of economic structure, Krugman (1991a, 1993d)
finds that the broad regions of the
Economic Integration and Regional
Specialization
The first problem concerns the evidence on regional
specialization. What is the
“regional” scale being referred to? The “regions” used by Krugman in his
comparisons of regional specialization and regional growth rate disparities in
the
In any case, is increasing regional industrial
specialization an inevitable outcome of economic integration? While the existence of external economies
and localization economies in the European Union could well lead to the
increased regional specialization that Krugman predicts (Baldwin and Lyons 1990;
Cabellero and Lyons 1990, 1991; Martin and Rogers 1994a, 1994b), some observers
have argued that product market integration in the European Union will increase
the
278
scope
of intraindustry trade there still further, and that this is likely to render
regional industrial structures increasingly similar over time (Commission
of the European Communities 1991; Eichengreen 1993; Emerson, Anjean, and Catinat
1988). Indeed, possible evidence
for this effect is provided for the
Economic Integration and Divergent Regional
Growth
This last point links with the third element of
Krugman’s thesis, that demand shocks in an integrated
Regions that have been unlucky in their heritage of
industries from the past will have lower costs than lucky regions, and will
therefore be more likely to break into industries in the future. We would expect this process to put
limits on the extent of regional divergence in growth. (Krugman 1993d,
248)
Unfortunately, however, according
to
22. There
is a sizable literature on this topic, although it is not referred to by Krugman
(for example, see Barth, Kraft, and Wiest 1975; Conroy 1975; Brewer 1984;
279
Krugman labor mobility prevents the wage flexibility
mechanism from bringing regional growth rates into balance in this
self-correcting way. To the
contrary:
An
unfortunate region will not have lower factor prices for very long: capital and
labour will move to other regions until payments are equalized. This means, however, that there is no
particular reason to expect a region whose traditional industries are faring
badly to attract new industries. It
can simply shed people instead. The
implication is that relative output and employment of regions should look more
like a random walk than like a process that returns to some norm. (Krugman
1993d, 248)
In developing this argument, Krugman draws on Blanchard
and Katz’s (1992) study of patterns of growth among
Labor mobility is thus central to Krugman’s model of
divergent regional growth. In this
respect his analysis is similar to local “endogenous growth” models, in which
labor mobility intensifies local disparities in the accumulation of human
capital and hence long-term development (Grossman and Helpman 1991; Bertola
1993). In this respect we find it
somewhat curious that Krugman is at pains to distinguish his model of uneven
regional development in the European Union not only from “core-periphery” models
of cumulative concentration but also from “local endogenous growth” models
(Krugman 1993d). His own model
implies a similar cumulative divergent growth mechanism, at least in the sense
that interregional shifts in labor prevent the reequilibration of regional
growth rates. The question mark
over his analysis is exactly how far labor mobility will increase in an
integrated
The implication of his model is that if labor mobility
is low, then local (downward) relative wage flexibility will serve to restrain
the degree of divergence between regional growth rates. Unfortunately, wages in the European
Union do not seem to be particularly flexible: European labor markets appear to be more
rigid or “sclerotic” than their American counterparts, a point highlighted by
Krugman (1993e). In the European
regions, adverse sectoral demand shocks trigger greater unemployment, without
the equilibrating mechanisms of labor migration or downward relative wage
movements (the rigidity of the latter possibly reflects the considerably higher
rates of institutionalized wage setting among workers and the availability of
more generous unemployment benefits in the EU countries compared to the
280
out
depressed regions, should encourage workers in such areas to moderate their wage
claims, thus imparting greater local wage flexibility. In practice, little is known about how
far regional relative wages would have to fall in order to stimulate capital
inflows and the restoration of employment. Equally, we still know little about
interregional productivity and technology spillovers, which may offset the need
for wage reductions (Jaffe, Trajtenberg, and Henderson 1993; Audretsch and
Feldman 1994). In short, it is by
no means obvious whether increasing integration in the European Union will lead
to convergence or divergence of regional growth. The evidence so far would seem to suggest
that “club convergence” may be the most likely outcome, with convergence within
the northern, core regions, on the one hand, and within the southern and
peripheral regions, on the other, but little or no convergence between these
subsets (Button and Pentecost 1993; Chatterji 1993; Neven and Gouyette
1994).
Thus, though suggestive, Krugman’s arguments about the
impact of economic integration on regional trade, specialization, instability,
and long-term growth disparities in the European Union are problematic and
limited. Comparison between the
United States and the European Union in terms of “regions” and their structures,
shocks and reactions to them is not, perhaps, as valid as Krugman and others
(such as Eichengreen) assume. We do
not have a counterfactual history for the