Compiler Press'

Elemental Economics

Not Accounting, Not Business, Not Commerce, Not Mathematics  - Economics  

                                                       

SITE INDEX

Microeconomics

Introductory

Intermediary

Shared Resources

Macroeconomics

Introductory

Intermediary

 

SISTERetrics

Cultural Econom

 SITES

Compiler Press

Compleat World Copyright Website

Competitiveness of Nations

Cultural Econom

ics

Elemental Economics

World Cultural Intelligence Network

 

Dr. Harry Hillman Chartrand, PhD

Cultural Economist & Publisher

Compiler Press

©

h.h.chartrand@compilerpress.ca

215 Lake Crescent

Saskatoon, Saskatchewan

Canada, S7H 3A1
 

Curriculum Vitae

 

Launched  1998

 

 

Introduction to Industrial Organization

MBA 7003

2.0 Structure

2.0 Structure

2.1 Market

Market Demand & Supply Curves   

Economic Surplus

Consumer

Producer

2.2 Perfect Competition

Anonymity

No Market Power

Perfect Knowledge

Free Entry & Exit

2.3 Monopolistic Competition

Market Niche/Segment

Market Power

Perfect Knowledge

Free Entry & Exit

2.4 Monopoly/Monopsony

One Seller/Buyer

Market Power

Perfect Knowledge

Barriers to Entry

Natural

Exclusive Input

IPRs

Franchise

2.5 Oligopoly/Oligopsony

Few Large Sellers/ Buyers

Market Power

Imperfect & Asymmetrical

        Knowledge

Barriers to Entry

2.6 Integration/Conglomerateness

2.7 Government Intervention

Anti-Trust & Combines

Equity& Regulation  

Non-Market Forces

Agriculture

Housing

Labour

Prohibited Goods

Taxation

In Industrial Organization every industry has a distinct Structure or organizational character.  The traditional elements of Structure are barriers to entry, the number and size distribution of firms, product differentiation and price elasticity of demand for its output.  An industry may have barriers to new firms entering in competition to existing firms.  Such barriers include economies of scale and of scope as well as exclusive possession of critical inputs to the production process.  This may be physical or legal possession in the form of intellectual property rights.  The number and size of firms also varies between industries. Some are competitive with many small firms, a.k.a, perfectly competitive with respect to price.  Others are oligopolies with a few large firms dominating the industry with a competitive fringe of smaller firms competing in niche markets. Some are effective monopolies with only one firm dominating the industry and a competitive fringe.  Similarly there are industries in which the output of each and every firm is judged homogenous by consumers - final and/or intermediary.  In other industries output by different firms is seen as distinct and different by consumers, e.g., through branding.

2.1 Market

The market is the basic structure of any industry.  It is any arrangement that enables buyers and sellers or consumers and producers to get information and do business with each other.  Put another way, markets are where demand meets supply.  Markets can be described by reference to whether they are:

- geographic, commodity or virtual, e.g., eBay;

- in or out of equilibrium;

- sensitive to change in prices and incomes (elasticity);

- influenced by an individual or group of consumes or producer;

- tightly or loosely regulated by government.

Market Demand & Supply Curves

First, however, we must aggregate the demand curves of all consumers and the supply curves of all producers to generate the market or industry supply curve.  Market demand is calculated as the horizontal summation of individual consumer demand curves, i.e. how much each individual consumer is willing to buy at each and every price.  It is important to note that the industry demand curve can thus be aggregated or disaggregated into market segments or niches.

The Law of Demand also holds for the market demand curve: the higher the price the lower the demand, the lower the price the higher the demand, It is assumed that there are constant prices for all other commodities as well as constant consumer income and constant consumer preference amongst alternative goods and services or commodities. 

Similarly, the market supply curve is calculated as the horizontal summation of the supply curves of all firms.  Market supply is calculated as the horizontal summation of the supply curves of individual firms, i.e. how much each individual firm is willing to supply at each and every price.  It is important to note that the industry supply curve can also be aggregated or disaggregated into market segments or niches.

With Market Demand and Supply Curves we generate an ‘X’-shaped graph with Demand increasing as price goes down and Supply increasing as price goes up.  There will be a point where the two intersect.  That is called market equilibrium, the point at which the willingness to buy and the willingness to sell are equal.  Ceteris paribus, this will be a stable equilibrium, i.e., if all variables remain fixed, e.g., technology, factor prices, consumer taste, income and the price of all other goods & services, the price-quantity equilibrium will be maintained.

Under such fixed conditions if the price rises, for whatever reason, above equilibrium firms will be willing to provide more than consumers are willing to buy.  A surplus is created. To eliminate the surplus firms lower price returning eventually to equilibrium.  Similarly, if price drops below equilibrium consumer demand exceeds supply and a shortage results. Consumers will then bid up the price until it returns to equilibrium. These are called ‘market forces’ (P&B 4th Ed. Fig. 4.8; 5th Ed. Fig. 3.7; 7th Ed Fig. 3.7 R&L 13th Ed Fig. 9-7).

The actual market outcome – price/quantity – will, however, depend on the nature of the market.  If there are many, many sellers of identical goods and many, many buyers there is ‘perfect competition’ and ‘X’ marks the spot.  If not, the outcome reflects the exercise of market power, i.e., the ability of one or more buyers or sellers to influence the final price/quantity outcome.

Economic Surplus

In a given market there will be gains of exchange enjoyed by both consumer and producer.  The total measures the economic surplus.

Consumer

Gains to consumer are called consumer surplus (P&B 4th Ed. Fig. 12.12; 7th Ed Fig 12.12b; R&L 13th Ed Fig. 12.4).  It measures the difference between what consumers would be willing to pay for a given quantity and what they actually pay.  Consumer surplus is measured as the area from market price up to the demand curve.

Producer

Gains to producers are called producer surplus (P&B 4th Ed. Fig. 12.12; 7th Ed Fig 12.12b; R&L 13th Ed Fig. 12.4).  It measures the difference between what firms would be willing to accept for a given quantity and what they actually receive.  Producer surplus is measured as the area from market price down to the supply curve.

We now turn to the four major industrial structures: perfect competition, monopolistic competition, monopoly/monopsony and oligopoly/oligopsony.  In this regard the concentration ratio can be used as a measure of industrial structure to indicate the form of competition in a given industry.  It is the percentage of total output supplied by a given number of the largest firms.  In the case of monopoly, for example, one firm supplies 100% of output.  In perfect competition and monopolistic competition the largest 100 firms might contribute just 10 or 20% of total output.  In oligopoly/oligopsony the largest 5 firms might account for 50 to 60% or more of total output.

2.2 Perfect Competition

Perfect competition satisfies four strict conditions:

Anonymity

Consumers are indistinguishable to producers.  Firms have no reason to favor one consumer over another.  The product of different firms is indistinguishable, one from another, in terms of price, quality and product differentiation.  They are 'homogenous'.  Consumers have no reason to prefer the product of one firm over that of another.  Similarly, any one consumer represents a tiny portion of market sales and producers have no reason to prefer one customer over another.

No Market Power

There is a large number of both producers and consumers.  Sales or purchases by any buyer or seller are small relative to the total volume of exchange.  No buyer or seller can affect price or quality, i.e., no one exercises market power.  All consumers and producers respond and adjust only to price signals.  The perfect competitor does not in fact face the market demand curve but rather market price.  The firm is thus a price taker rather than a price maker.  It can sell as much as it wants at market price but loses all business if it raises the price of its homogenous output (P&B 4th Ed. Fig 12.1; 5th Ed Fig. 11.1; 7th Ed Fig. 12.1).

Perfect Knowledge

Consumers and producers possess perfect knowledge about price and quality.  No firm can charge more, and no consumer can pay less than the market equilibrium price.

Free Entry & Exit

Entry and exit from the market is free for both consumers and producers.  There is an unimpeded flow of resources between alternative uses i.e., resources are mobile and move to the use with greatest advantage in terms of opportunity costs.   Firms exit if they experience ‘economic’ loss.  Thereby inefficient firms are eliminated from the market.  Firms enter the market if they expect to earn economic short-run, and/or, normal long run profits.  On the demand side of the Marshallian scissors, there are many close substitutes available to consumers who can easily switch if price, preference and/or income changes.

2.3 Monopolistic Competition

Monopolistic competition satisfies two conditions of perfect competition but fails to satisfy two others.

Market Niche/Segment

As in perfect competition there are a large number of sellers.  The output of firms is not, however, considered homogenous by consumers.  Rather they are differentiated.  Consider the restaurant industry.  Hamburgers and hot dogs are not the same as pizza or fried chicken.  Some consumers prefer one or the other.  In effect, the market demand curve is disaggregated into distinct market niches or segments. 

Market Power  

Within each niche a firm faces a downward sloping demand curve for its product, i.e., they can sell more if they lower price and less if they raise it.  A seller therefore possesses market power, i.e., the ability to influence the price/quantity outcome, depending on the elasticity of demand.   

Perfect Knowledge  

As in perfect competition, consumers and producers possess perfect knowledge about price and quality including product differentiation. 

Free Entry & Exit

As in perfect competition, under monopolistic competition entry and exit from the market is free for both consumers and producers.  There are no barriers to entry or exit.  There is an unimpeded flow of resources between alternative uses i.e., resources are mobile and move to the use with greatest advantage in terms of opportunity costs.   Firms exit if they experience ‘economic’ loss.  Thereby inefficient firms are eliminated from the market.  Firms enter the market if they expect to earn economic short-run, and/or, normal long run profits.  On the demand side of the Marshallian Scissors, there are many close substitutes available to consumers who can easily switch if price, preference and/or income changes.

2.4 Monopoly/Monopsony

Monopoly and monopsony satisfy one and fail to satisfy three conditions of perfect competition.

One Seller/Buyer

There is, in the case of monopoly, no distinction between the firm and the industry, i.e. there is only one producer.  In the case of monopsony, there is no distinction between the single consumer and the industry.  An example of monopsony is the U.S. Air Force, the only buyer of B2 bombers.

Market Power

In monopoly, one producer faces the market demand curve and can accordingly sell more if it lowers its price and sell less if it raises it.  In monopsony, one buyer faces the market supply curve and can buy more if it pays a higher price and less if it pays a lower one.

The monopolist is able to choose the price-quantity combination to maximize its profits, i.e., it is a price maker.  Monopoly power is mitigated only by competition from substitutes.  The closer the substitutes the less market power is available to the monopolist.  Similarly, the monopsonist can choose which price/quantity outcome will minimize its cost.

There are, however, two types of monopoly, i.e., a single price and discriminating monopolist.  The single price monopolist sells output at the same price to all consumers.  The discriminating monopolist, on the other hand, disaggregates the market demand curve into individual consumer demand curves.  It can then charge a different price to each individual consumer extracting the maximum of consumer surplus from each individual consumer.  In effect the discriminating monopolist is able to play on the willingness of consumers to pay a higher price for a smaller quantity due to diminishing marginal utility.

Perfect Knowledge

As in perfect competition, consumers and the monopolist both possess perfect knowledge about price and quality including substitutes. 

Barriers to Entry

Monopoly exists for one, or more, of four reasons.  First, a firm may become a monopolist because economies of scale allow the monopolist reach an output level sufficient to supply the entire market at minimum average cost per unit.  This is a natural monopoly (P&B 4th Ed Fig. 13.1; 5th Ed. Fig. 12.1; 7th Ed Fig. 13.1; R&L 13th Ed not displayed).  Second, one firm may control the entire supply of a basic input.  An example would be a mineral critical to production of the good in question and the monopolist owns the only mine producing that input.   Third, a firm may acquire control over a product due to an intellectual property right - copyright, patent, registered industrial design or trademark - granted by the State.  Fourth, a firm may become a monopolist because government awards an exclusive market franchise, e.g. electric power, water supply, etc.

A monopolist is not, however, entirely insulated from the economy as a whole.  All commodities are rivals for the consumer’s limited income.  The closer are substitutes, the greater the moderating influence on a monopolist.  The threat of entry by outsiders interested in gaining some of the monopolist’s excess profits also serves to moderate pricing behavior, e.g. the threat that cable companies could offer telephone service will limit the pricing of a telephone monopolist.  

2.5 Oligopoly/Oligopsony

Oligopoly/oligopsony satisfies none of the conditions of perfect competition.

Few Large Sellers/ Buyers

In the case of oligopoly, there is a small number of large firms that dominate the industry.  Often these majors are surrounded by a competitive fringe of smaller firms usually operating in distinct market niches or segments.   The action of a major producer is perceptible to rivals, i.e. there is interdependency of sellers whereby an action by one results in reaction of others.  Furthermore, the output of producers is not seen as homogenous by consumers.  This is often the result of successful branding.  Thus each major enjoys a certain market share based on product differentiation.

In the case of oligopsony, there is a small number of large buyers that dominate the industry.  Often these majors are surrounded by a competitive fringe of smaller buyers, again usually operating in distinct market niches or segments.   The action of a major buyer is perceptible to rivals, i.e. there is interdependency of sellers whereby an action by one results in reaction of others.  An example of an oligopsony are the ‘big box stores’ like Walmart, Target, Safeway, etc.  Due to the scale of there purchases they can influence the price/quantity outcome at which they buy from suppliers.

Market Power   

Due to economies of scale, product differentiation like branding as well as process/product innovation, oligopolists exercise market power in determining the equilibrium price/quantity relationship in a market.

Imperfect & Asymmetrical Knowledge

Unlike perfect competition, consumers as well as oligopolists and oligopsonists do not possess perfect knowledge.  Specifically, they do not know how or when other players will react to the actions of a major.  For example, if Ford Motor Company offers zero percent APR (above prime rate) financing will Toyota respond the same way or choose an alternative strategy like a long warranty?  This opens up the question of asymmetrical information including issues such as insider trading.

Barriers to Entry

Oligopoly/Oligopsony also exhibit barriers to the entry of new firms.  Economies of scale can thus inhibit entry.  Product differentiation through branding can also make it difficult for a new firm to enter the industry.  And, as will be seen under 4. Performance, the excess or economic profits earned by oligopolists allow them to invest in advertising – branding – as well as product and process innovation.  A lean, mean, perfectly competitive firm can afford neither.

2.6 Integration/Conglomerateness

In Microeconomic theory we are dealing with a single product, profit maximizing firm.  In Industrial Organization we are dealing with real world industrial structures which include vertical, horizontal and conglomerate integration.

Vertical integration unites under one owner a number of plants engaged in successive processes or stages of production.  An example is a vertically integrated oil company co-temporally engaged in exploration, production, refining and retailing.  Horizontal integration unites under one owner a number of plants engaged in the same processes or stage of production.  An example is a multi-plant firm engaged in metal fabrication.  Output becomes an input to other industries which combine them with yet other inputs in their own production process.

Conglomerateness, on the other hand, involves diversification beyond the boundaries of any given industry.  Conglomerate mergers were the rage in the United States during the 1960s because anti-trust policies inhibited significant concentration due to either vertical or horizontal mergers.  With fat profits in their corporate pockets many firms argued that ‘management’ was the ultimate economic resource.  If one could manage steel then one could manage airlines, chocolate bars or any other business.  In effect, local knowledge was considered less important than management in building a business success.  With the notable exception of General Electric most conglomerate mergers of the ‘60s failed. 

2.7 Government Intervention

Government intervention is a pervasive structural characteristic of all industries and markets.  The form and nature of that intervention takes varying forms.  Bankruptcy, environmental, financial, health & safety, incorporation, labour and protection of persons & property are just some of the areas in which government plays an active role in every industry.  I will first argue that equity provides both the legal and economic rationale for governmental intervention.  I will then highlight non-market forces unleashed by certain forms of governmental intervention, specifically price setting.

Anti-Trust & Combines in a Global Economy

from 50s to Globalization

Equity & Regulation

Courts of Common Law are one of the great contributions of the Anglosphere.  Formally beginning in the reign of Henry II in the 12th century, Common Law, unlike Statutory and Regulatory Law, originates in the Anglosphere.  Two things make Common Law different.  First, judges may “make” Law by setting precedents.  The body of precedent is called “common law”.  If a similar case was resolved in the past, a current court is bound to follow the reasoning of that prior decision on the principle of stare decisis.  The process is called casuistry or case-based reasoning.  If a current case is different, however, then a judge may set a precedent binding future courts in similar cases.  Casuistry must begin again, however, if changes or amendments to Statutory or Regulatory Law negate the precedent. 

Second, Common Law is rooted in trial by jury, i.e., one’s peers.  This is a fundamental civil right in the Anglosphere in criminal law.  By contrast, the European Civil Code tradition is based on trial by judge/prosecutor, i.e., the police and judicial functions merge in one office.  On the other hand, the impresciptible moral rights of authors are recognized under Civil Code but not Common Law.  Similarly there is the treatment of torts, i.e., non-contractual rights and obligations.  Under Common Law they are treated by precedent and trial ‘attorneys’ in the U.S.A. enjoy a large practice.  Under Civil Code such questions are answered by principle, somewhat like equity in the Anglsophere.

However, at the same time the Common Law arose during the resign of Henry II another unique Anglosphere juridical institution emerged – Equity.   It was not guilt or innocence but fairness of punishment before the King.  This is the root of Equity – a separate and distinct strand of jurisprudence parallel to the Common Law of precedent.

Over time responsibility for hearing calls for mercy was transferred to the King’s Lord Chancellor and a court of his own – the Court of Equity also known as the Court of Conscience or of Morality.  In fact until Sir Thomas More (a lawyer) became Chancellor in 1529, all had been men of the cloth.  Two aspects of Equity played a critical role in the Sovereign’s ability to control his vassals.  These were trusts and tenant-landlord disputes. Trusts (from which modern charities and financial trusts evolved) generally concerned widows and orphans left to the mercy of a local lord.  The most famous is Lady Marion of the Robin Hood legend who was an orphan and ward of the King.  With respect to tenant-landlord disputes, Equity balanced the feudal local lords by judiciously connecting the King to his subjects.  This was called the ‘rent bargain’ by J.R. Commons (1924).  It stabilized the social system of post-Conquest England.

While Magna Carta (1215) and subsequent developments increasingly limited the King, Equity and Common Law continued to develop as parallel systems of courts with precedence given to Equity.  It was not until 1873 in the United Kingdom that the two systems of courts merged, i.e., cases at Equity could be heard by the same courts that ruled under Common Law.  Nonetheless the two strands of Anglosphere jurisprudence continue to this day in all Common Law countries with Equity retaining precedence. 

The economic concept of Equity arguably derives from legal Equity.  In fact the Chancellor of the Exchequer exercised a concurrent jurisdiction in Equity with the Lord Chancellor’s Court.  There are three economic definitions of Equity, each reflecting its historical roots.  First, there is Equity as the capital of a firm which, after deducting liabilities to outsiders, belongs to the shareholders.  Hence shares in a limited liability corporation are also known as equities.  This links back to the historical treatment of trusts under Equity.

Second, there is Equity as ‘fairness’.  While often used with reference to taxation it is a general economic concept.  With respect to taxation Equity has three dimensions: horizontal, vertical and overall burden.  Horizontal Equity refers to ‘like treatment of like’.  Vertical Equity refers to ‘unlike treatment of unlike’.  Overall Equity refers to the accumulated impact of all forms of taxation.  Crudely, it is the difference between earned and disposable income after all taxes – income, excise, sales, et al. 

Equity thus provides the legal and economic rational for government intervention in the economy.  Such interventions include, of course, the Corporations Act and Bankruptcy Act.  It also justifies anti-trust and anti-combines legislation to counter the exercise of market power. 

Non-Market Forces

We have seen that if a competitive market is allowed to operate an equilibrium price/quantity outcome will result from the interplay of market force.  If price is too high, Supply exceeds Demand and a surplus is created.  To get rid of the surplus producers must lower their price, eventually to equilibrium.  Similarly, if price is below equilibrium then Demand exceeds Supply and a shortage is created.  Consumers wanting the good bid up its price back to equilibrium. 

What happens, however, if government intervenes and does not allow market forces to function?  I will now consider such price setting intervention in agriculture, housing, labour, prohibited goods and taxation.

Agriculture

Agriculture is subject to significant fluctuations in supply yet a relatively inelastic demand, people have to eat. We begin by assuming only domestic production is involved. In any given year, the supply is fixed and perfectly inelastic, a harvest is the harvest is the harvest. In an unregulated market (P&B 4th Ed. Fig. 7.11; 5th Ed. Fig. 6.11; 7th Ed not displayed;. R&L 13th Ed not displayed), a bad harvest shifts supply to the left. This raises prices and will actually increase revenue to the farmer. A bumper crop, on the other hand, will shift supply to the right, lower prices and reduce farm income.

Many agricultural commodities can be stored, that is placed in inventory. Inventories serve to stabilize prices between growing seasons. Without inventories the above situation applies, that is a good harvest lowers prices, a bad harvest raises prices. Inventories reduce these price fluctuations (P&B 4th Ed. Fig. 7.12; 5th Ed. Fig. 6.12; 7th Ed not displayed;. R&L 13th Ed not displayed). A good harvest can be used to increase inventories, that is, not all output goes to market and price decreases are moderated. In the case of a bad harvest, inventories are sold, thereby increasing supply and reducing price increases.

A price floor acts like a minimum wage. If the floor is less than market equilibrium, it has no effect. If it is greater than equilibrium price it will create a demand gap between the larger amount suppliers are willing to provide at the floor price, and the quantity consumers are willing to buy (P&B 4th Ed. Fig. 7.13; 5th Ed. Fig. 6.13; 7th Ed not displayed;. R&L 13th 5-2).

Quotas (on eggs, grain, beef, etc.) act like a perfectly inelastic supply curve (P&B 4th Ed. Fig 7.14; 5th Ed. Fig. 6.14; P&B 7th Ed Fig. 6.11;. R&L 13th 5-8). If the quota output is less than equilibrium output the price will be higher and the supply lower. This creates a supply gap where producers have an incentive to exceed their quota. This can lead to increased

Subsidies act like a reverse tax (P&B 4th Ed. Fig. 7.15; 5th Ed. Fig. 6.15; P&B 7th Ed Fig. 6.12; R&L 13th Ed not displayed). The tend to shift the supply curve to the right. Output increases and prices fall. Such 'supply-side' subsidies financially reward increased production by offering subsidies per bushel of output or per acre planted. This approach has led to a frightening subsidy spiral. In effect, production subsidies reduce the final price of farm output below the cost of production. This, in turn, means that even efficient farmers cannot earn enough to maintain operations. This, in turn, leads to more subsidies that lower prices further. And, so on and so on and so on...

Housing

Part of the short-run adjustment process involves price, that is, if demand exceeds supply, prices will tend to rise. In the case of rental property, which tends to be the type of housing available to the poorer members of a community, a price rise takes the form of rent increases. If government decides for reasons of vertical equity (unlike treatment of persons in unlike situations) that the poor need to be protected from rent increases (or for political reasons, there are more poor voters than landowners) then it may impose rent controls in the form of a rent ceiling (P&B 4th Ed. Fig. 7.2; 5th Ed. Fig. 6.2; 7th Ed Fig. 6.1 & Fig. 6.2;. R&L 13th 5-3 & 5-4).

In effect, rent control imposes a price which is less than that determined by the market. This means that demand (the willingness of consumers to pay) exceeds the supply (the willingness of producer to supply). This results in a housing shortage. Because demand exceeds supply yet price can not increase other forms of behaviour take the place of a price increase. For example, given a shortage:

i - consumers must search harder and harder to find supply when it does become available. Search activity is costly; and/or,

ii - consumers will 'bribe' supplier, for example, by paying more 'on the side'; by accepting little or no maintenance or support services; by accepting 'run down conditions'.

The effect of rent control is to reduce the return to suppliers. If they cannot cut back production directly they may do so indirectly. First, new rental accommodation will not be built which, if population continues to grow, accentuates the shortage. Second, existing rental property will be allowed to 'run down', eventually into 'slum condition'. With excess demand and a fixed price, the supplier can recoup his or her opportunity cost by running the building down until it is uninhabitable, then tear it down and build private homes or condos for sale on an open and competitive market without price controls. This again accentuates the housing shortage.

Labour

Low wages for unskilled labour may create a question of vertical equity (or political reasons). Government may decide that with such low wages unskilled workers cannot support themselves, their children and/or other dependents above the 'poverty line'. Accordingly government may intervene by establishing a 'minimum wage rate'.

If this rate is below market equilibrium rate such a minimum has no real effect. If, however, it is above the market equilibrium price (P&B 4th Ed. Fig. 7.5; 5th Ed. Fig. 6.5; 7th Ed Fig. 6.3 & Fig. 6.4;. R&L 13th p. 103, no JPEG available) the supply of willing workers exceeds the demand of producers. As in the case of rent controls, if the price cannot adjust, other forms of behaviour will evolve. For example, some workers will offer to work some hours 'off the books'.

Prohibited Goods

While some goods like recreational drugs are illegal and hence prohibited, a market exist. To understand the effect of prohibition, we begin with market equilibrium assuming no prohibition (P&B 4th Ed. Fig. 7.10; 5th Ed. Fig. 6.10; P&B 7th Ed Fig. 6.13; R&L 13th 5-3). A prohibition affect both demand and supply. It imposes penalties, that is costs, on both. The effect is to shift the supply curve up to the left and shift the demand curve down to the left.

Taxation

To finance public spending (a pleasure), government must raise revenue through taxes (a pain). This pleasure/pain of public finance is described in the Introduction: The Pleasure & Pain of Public Finance to my paper "A Radical Analysis of 'Personal' Taxation." An increasingly important source of tax revenue is sales tax, for example, the GST and provincial sales tax. The question arises: who pays Is it the consumer or the producer or both?

Consumer demand does not change if a sales tax is imposed. The demand curve reflects the quantity of a good or service consumers are willing to buy at a given price. If the price goes up, one slides up the demand curve; if the price goes down, one slides down the demand curve - all things being equal. Accordingly, to the consumer the real price of a good is its retail price plus any associated taxes.

A sales tax does, however, shift the supply curve up to the left. Producers are willing to supply a certain quantity of goods or services if the receive a given price. With sales tax, such goods and services are offered for sale at a higher price (P&B 4th Ed. Fig. 7.6; 5th Ed. Fig. 6.6; 7th Ed Fig. 6.5; R&L 13th Ed Fig. 4-8 & 4-9). The supply curve shifts and a new equilibrium is established at a higher price and a lower quantity than before the tax.

As to who pays the tax, the answer depends on the elasticity of supply and demand. If there is perfectly inelastic demand, for example for a 'necessity', the demand curve is vertical (P&B 4th Ed. Fig. 7.7a; 5th Ed. Fig. 6.7; 7th Ed Fig. 6.7) In this case the consumer pays the full tax. If, on the other hand, demand is perfectly elastic ((P&B 4th Ed. Fig. 7.7b; 5th Ed. Fig. 6.7; 7th Ed Fig. 6.8; R&L 13th Ed Fig. 4-8 & 4-9), then the producer pays the whole tax.

In the case of supply elasticity, the situation is reversed (P&B 4th Ed. Fig. 7.8; 5th Ed. Fig. 6.8; 7th Ed Fig. 6.9). If supply is totally inelastic, that is the supply curve is vertical, then the supplier bares the full tax. If supply is perfectly elastic, however, the consumer will pay the tax

 

to 3.0 Conduct