Edward
Shapiro
The
MACROECONOMIC
ANALYSIS
Second
Edition
Under
the Editorship of
WILLIAM J.
BAUMOL
HARCOURT,
BRACE & WORLD, INC.
CHAPTER 17, pp. 338-363
Homepage
Index Web 1 THE CLASSICAL THEORY
The Level of Output and
Employment in Classical Theory Say’s
Law The Quantity Theory of
Money
The Quantity Theory as a Theory of the Price
Level The Quantity Theory as a Theory of Aggregate Demand Classical Model without
Saving and Investment
Effects of a Change in the Supply of Money
Effect of a Change in the Supply of Labor
Effects of a Change in the Demand for Labor
Effects of a Rigid Money Wage Monetary Policy and Full Employment Classical Model with Saving
and Investment
Saving and Investment
Changes in Saving and Investment Summary
Statement |
THE CLASSICAL
THEORY
The Keynesian conclusion
that the equilibrium output level may be below the level that provides full
employment for the labor force appears to be quite plausible on the basis of the
arguments developed in Chapter 16. The conclusion that an economy’s
equilibrium level of output would be only the level that provides full
employment of its labor force appeared equally plausible to many generations of
economists before the appearance of Keynes’s General Theory.
1 There were,
of course, dissenters who argued against this conclusion long before Keynes did,
but, nonetheless, the theory that aggregate demand simply could not be deficient
became widely accepted.
In this chapter we will
examine an abbreviated model of the theory that denied the possibility of
deficient aggregate demand and underemployment equilibrium, the theory that
Keynes called the “classical” theory. Although our model is a classical one,
the form in which we present it will nowhere be found in the writings of
Ricardo, Mill, Marshall, or any of the other economists who were the creators
and refiners of the classical theory. It was not until after the appearance of
the General Theory that economists set to work to construct from the
writings of the classical theorists complete models that might be placed side by
side with the Keynesian model for comparison. Since, for simplicity, we will limit
ourselves to the broad outlines of that classical model, we must note that our
inattention to specific details amounts to inattention to the many
qualifications that must be made to the conclusions we will draw. Nonetheless, the conclusions reached on
this basis will at least suggest the directions in which the classical theory
led.
The classical theory, whose
broad outlines are described in this chapter,
1. John Maynard Keynes,
The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, Harcourt, Brace
& World, 1936.
338
is specifically classical
theory as it was before Keynes’s General Theory. As we will see below, the quantity
theory of money is an essential part of classical theory, but today there is a
“modern” version of quantity theory that differs markedly from the old version
that was part of traditional classical theory. We will touch on the modern version in a
later chapter; here our purpose is to cover the essentials of classical theory
before Keynes, and so it is the “old” quantity theory that is examined as a part
of that theory.
Our classical model is also
limited to the classical explanations of the determination of employment,
output, and price levels, for it was these explanations that came under attack
by Keynes and others. The other
basic questions of what is to be produced, how it is to be produced, and for
whom it is to be produced provoked no disagreement. In Keynes’s
words:
If we suppose the volume of
output to be given, i.e. to be determined by forces outside the classical scheme
of thought, then there is no objection to be raised against the classical
analysis of the manner in which private self-interest will determine what in
particular is produced, in what proportions the factors of production will be
combined to produce it, and how the value of the final product will be
distributed between them. 2
Beyond this, not all
classical theory relating to the determination of aggregate output and
employment was disputed by Keynes. We have encountered parts of this
generally accepted theory in the incomplete Keynesian model already developed.
Here we will bring in the other
elements of the classical theory and show how it led to the conclusion of
automatic full employment.
THE LEVEL OF OUTPUT AND
EMPLOYMENT IN CLASSICAL
THEORY
The equilibrium level of
output and employment are determined in the classical system as soon as we are
given (1) the economy’s production function, from which is derived the demand
curve for labor, and (2) the supply curve of labor. Parts A and B of Figure 17-1 are similar
to Parts A and B of Figure l6-l.
The MPP-of-labor curve, labeled DL in Figure 17-1, is
as before derived from the production function and shows that the MPP of labor
decreases due to diminishing returns as the amount of labor employed
increases. Since employers maximize
profits by hiring labor up to the point at which MPP X P = W, at
2. General Theory,
pp. 378-79. This is not to say,
however, that the theory of distribution that was developed by classical
economists is the last word. Although Keynes accepted this part of
classical theory for his purposes, the very ground broken by Keynes in the
theory of aggregate output and employment gave rise to a new interest in the
macroeconomic aspects of income distribution. See, for example, S. Weintraub, A
General Theory of the Price Level, Output, Income, Distribution, and Economic
Growth, Chilton, 1959, and N. Kaldor, “Alternative Theories of
Distribution,” in Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 23,
1955-56.
339
any given W more
labor will be hired beyond an initial equilibrium only at a higher P, or
at any given P more labor will be hired only at a lower W.
3 The level of
employment consistent with profit maximization may alternatively be described as
the level at which MPP = W/P or the level at which MPP equals the
real wage (which is the ratio of the money wage to the price level). Thus we might say that the amount of
labor hired is an inverse function of the real wage. With a given production function and an
initial equilibrium at which MPP = W/P, an increase in employment is not
possible without a decrease in the real wage.
Keynes could find no fault
with this postulate of classical theory, and in effect we adopted it in our
Keynesian analysis of the determination of output and employment in Chapter
16. However, as we noted there,
Keynes did argue that general cuts in money wage rates would ordinarily be
incapable of eliminating unemployment, because, he held, such cuts in money wage
rates would lead to proportionate declines in the price level, P, and
leave the real wage, W/P, unchanged. Thus, while Keynes agreed with classical
theory that a reduction in the real wage was a prerequisite to an increase in
employment, he did not agree that such a reduction could be secured through
general cuts in money wage rates.
As will be developed below, classical theory holds that cuts in money
wage rates do not led to proportionate declines in the
price
3. see pp.
313-15.
340
level, so, in that theory,
cuts in money wage rates become a means of reducing the real wage and thereby a
means of eliminating unemployment.
The curve
SL in Figure 17-1 shows that the labor supply is, like the
demand for labor, DL, a function of the real wage
W/P. But the labor supply is
a direct rather than an inverse function of the real wage. This expresses the contention that a
higher money wage will not call forth more labor if the price level rises
proportionately, for in this event the real wage remains unchanged. For the same reason a lower money wage
matched by a proportionate fall in the price level will not lead to a reduction
in the quantity of labor supplied.
The basis for this postulate of classical theory is the unpleasantness or
irksomeness of more work; a larger real reward is necessary to induce
labor to provide an ever larger supply of labor
services.
Workers, as well as the
firms that employ them, are maximizing units in this system. Firms will not hire more labor at a lower
money wage rate if the prices at which they can sell their output falls
proportionately with the money wage rate. Of relevance to the firm is the cost of a
unit of labor relative to the price at which the firm’s output sells -it is the
real wage that counts. By the same
token, workers will not supply more labor at a higher money wage rate if the
prices of the goods purchased with their wages rise proportionately with the
money wage rate. Of relevance to
the worker is the money wage received per .unit of labor supplied relative to
the prices of the goods that can be purchased with that money wage - it is the
real wage that counts. This
maximizing behavior on either side of the market for labor gives us the demand
curve for labor as an inverse function of the real wage and the supply curve as
a direct function of the real wage.
The intersection of the
supply and demand curves for labor determines the level of employment and the
real wage and, one step removed, the level of aggregate output. With a real wage of
(W/P)1 in Figure 17-1, there is equilibrium between the supply
of and demand for labor. At this
real wage, employers choose to hire N1 of labor and workers
choose to provide N1 of labor. With the aggregate production function
of Part A, employment of N1 indicates aggregate output of
O1.
In the classical scheme of
things, any real wage other than (W/P)1 in a system of
competitive markets will generate forces causing the real wage to rise or fall
by the amount necessary to establish equilibrium in the labor market. Assume, for example, that the real wage
is (W/P)2, at which real wage the quantity of labor supplied
is N3 and the quantity demanded is N2. To achieve equilibrium there must be
a fall in the real wage, and this may be accomplished by an appropriate decline
in W, a rise in P, or some combination of the
two.4 A fall in W
follows from the excess of supply over demand for labor, which leads to
competition among workers for jobs. This causes workers to offer their
services at a lower money wage, and a falling money wage, on the
assumption
4. We will later see that
adjustment could be brought about entirely by a rising price level, but since we
have not yet worked into the analysis the classical theory of the determination
of the price level, it is best at this point to assume a constant price
level.
341
of a constant price level,
means a falling real wage. A
falling real wage means that employers find it profitable to hire more labor (a
movement down the demand curve) and that workers choose to supply less labor (a
movement down the supply curve). Once the money wage has fallen by the
amount necessary to reduce the real wage from (W/P)2 to
(W/P)1, equilibrium is reached. Employment has risen from N2
to N1, and output has risen from O2
to O1. If we had assumed instead an
initial real wage below the equilibrium real wage, the adjustment process would
be similar. However, in this case
there would bean excess demand for labor and competition among employers that
would bid up the money wage by the amount necessary to raise the real wage to
its equilibrium level.
The equilibrium level of employment so determined is also the full-employment leve1; that is, at this level all those who are able, willing, and seeking to work at prevailing wage rates are employed. Since any other leve1 of employment is a disequilibrium level, a familiar proposition of classical theory is that the equilibrium position in the market for labor is necessarily one of full employment. Whatever unemployment, apart from frictional unemployment, persists in the face of this equilibrium must be voluntary unemployment. For example, with the equilibrium real wage established at (W/P)1, any persons who are unemployed are considered to be voluntarily unemployed if they are seeking work but will accept work only at a money wage that, at the existing price level, means a real wage greater than (W/P)1. They are seeking a real wage that is inconsistent with the marginal productivity of their labor, and in effect they are “pricing” themselves out of the market. Given our previous assumption of a constant price level, there is in the classical system no barrier to full employment or to the elimination of involuntary unemployment as long as labor is willing to reduce its money wage as required to produce that real wage at which all who wish to work will be hired.
342