Edward Shapiro

The University of Toledo\

 

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS

Second Edition

Under the Editorship of

WILLIAM J. BAUMOL

Princeton University

HARCOURT, BRACE & WORLD, INC.

New York Chicago San Francisco Atlanta 1970

 

                 CHAPTER 17, pp. 338-363

Articles Homepage

Index

Web 1

THE CLASSICAL THEORY

The Level of Output and Employment in Classical Theory

Web 2

Say’s Law

The Quantity Theory of Money

             The Quantity Theory as a Theory of the Price Level

             The Quantity Theory as a Theory of Aggregate Demand

Web 3

Classical Model without Saving and Investment

             Effects of a Change in the Supply of Money

             Effect of a Change in the Supply of Labor

             Effects of a Change in the Demand for Labor

             Effects of a Rigid Money Wage

             Monetary Policy and Full Employment

Web 4

Classical Model with Saving and Investment

             Saving and Investment

             Changes in Saving and Investment

Summary Statement

THE CLASSICAL THEORY

The Keynesian conclusion that the equilibrium output level may be below the level that provides full employment for the labor force appears to be quite plausible on the basis of the arguments developed in Chapter 16.  The conclusion that an economy’s equilibrium level of output would be only the level that provides full employment of its labor force appeared equally plausible to many generations of economists before the appearance of Keynes’s General Theory. 1  There were, of course, dissenters who argued against this conclusion long before Keynes did, but, nonetheless, the theory that aggregate demand simply could not be deficient became widely accepted.

In this chapter we will examine an abbreviated model of the theory that denied the possibility of deficient aggregate demand and underemployment equilibrium, the theory that Keynes called the “classical” theory.  Although our model is a classical one, the form in which we present it will nowhere be found in the writings of Ricardo, Mill, Marshall, or any of the other economists who were the creators and refiners of the classical theory.  It was not until after the appearance of the General Theory that economists set to work to construct from the writings of the classical theorists complete models that might be placed side by side with the Keynesian model for comparison.  Since, for simplicity, we will limit ourselves to the broad outlines of that classical model, we must note that our inattention to specific details amounts to inattention to the many qualifications that must be made to the conclusions we will draw.  Nonetheless, the conclusions reached on this basis will at least suggest the directions in which the classical theory led.

The classical theory, whose broad outlines are described in this chapter,

1. John Maynard Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, Harcourt, Brace & World, 1936.

338

is specifically classical theory as it was before Keynes’s General Theory.  As we will see below, the quantity theory of money is an essential part of classical theory, but today there is a “modern” version of quantity theory that differs markedly from the old version that was part of traditional classical theory.  We will touch on the modern version in a later chapter; here our purpose is to cover the essentials of classical theory before Keynes, and so it is the “old” quantity theory that is examined as a part of that theory.

Our classical model is also limited to the classical explanations of the determination of employment, output, and price levels, for it was these explanations that came under attack by Keynes and others.  The other basic questions of what is to be produced, how it is to be produced, and for whom it is to be produced provoked no disagreement.  In Keynes’s words:

If we suppose the volume of output to be given, i.e. to be determined by forces outside the classical scheme of thought, then there is no objection to be raised against the classical analysis of the manner in which private self-interest will determine what in particular is produced, in what proportions the factors of production will be combined to produce it, and how the value of the final product will be distributed between them. 2

Beyond this, not all classical theory relating to the determination of aggregate output and employment was disputed by Keynes.  We have encountered parts of this generally accepted theory in the incomplete Keynesian model already developed.  Here we will bring in the other elements of the classical theory and show how it led to the conclusion of automatic full employment.

 Index

 

THE LEVEL OF OUTPUT AND EMPLOYMENT IN CLASSICAL THEORY

The equilibrium level of output and employment are determined in the classical system as soon as we are given (1) the economy’s production function, from which is derived the demand curve for labor, and (2) the supply curve of labor.  Parts A and B of Figure 17-1 are similar to Parts A and B of Figure l6-l.  The MPP-of-labor curve, labeled DL in Figure 17-1, is as before derived from the production function and shows that the MPP of labor decreases due to diminishing returns as the amount of labor employed increases.  Since employers maximize profits by hiring labor up to the point at which MPP X P = W, at

2. General Theory, pp. 378-79.  This is not to say, however, that the theory of distribution that was developed by classical economists is the last word.  Although Keynes accepted this part of classical theory for his purposes, the very ground broken by Keynes in the theory of aggregate output and employment gave rise to a new interest in the macroeconomic aspects of income distribution.  See, for example, S. Weintraub, A General Theory of the Price Level, Output, Income, Distribution, and Economic Growth, Chilton, 1959, and N. Kaldor, “Alternative Theories of Distribution,” in Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 23, 1955-56.

339

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

any given W more labor will be hired beyond an initial equilibrium only at a higher P, or at any given P more labor will be hired only at a lower W. 3  The level of employment consistent with profit maximization may alternatively be described as the level at which MPP = W/P or the level at which MPP equals the real wage (which is the ratio of the money wage to the price level).  Thus we might say that the amount of labor hired is an inverse function of the real wage.  With a given production function and an initial equilibrium at which MPP = W/P, an increase in employment is not possible without a decrease in the real wage.

Keynes could find no fault with this postulate of classical theory, and in effect we adopted it in our Keynesian analysis of the determination of output and employment in Chapter 16.  However, as we noted there, Keynes did argue that general cuts in money wage rates would ordinarily be incapable of eliminating unemployment, because, he held, such cuts in money wage rates would lead to proportionate declines in the price level, P, and leave the real wage, W/P, unchanged.  Thus, while Keynes agreed with classical theory that a reduction in the real wage was a prerequisite to an increase in employment, he did not agree that such a reduction could be secured through general cuts in money wage rates.  As will be developed below, classical theory holds that cuts in money wage rates do not led to proportionate declines in the price

3. see pp. 313-15.

340  Index

level, so, in that theory, cuts in money wage rates become a means of reducing the real wage and thereby a means of eliminating unemployment.

The curve SL in Figure 17-1 shows that the labor supply is, like the demand for labor, DL, a function of the real wage W/P.  But the labor supply is a direct rather than an inverse function of the real wage.  This expresses the contention that a higher money wage will not call forth more labor if the price level rises proportionately, for in this event the real wage remains unchanged.  For the same reason a lower money wage matched by a proportionate fall in the price level will not lead to a reduction in the quantity of labor supplied.  The basis for this postulate of classical theory is the unpleasantness or irksomeness of more work; a larger real reward is necessary to induce labor to provide an ever larger supply of labor services.

Workers, as well as the firms that employ them, are maximizing units in this system.  Firms will not hire more labor at a lower money wage rate if the prices at which they can sell their output falls proportionately with the money wage rate.  Of relevance to the firm is the cost of a unit of labor relative to the price at which the firm’s output sells -it is the real wage that counts.  By the same token, workers will not supply more labor at a higher money wage rate if the prices of the goods purchased with their wages rise proportionately with the money wage rate.  Of relevance to the worker is the money wage received per .unit of labor supplied relative to the prices of the goods that can be purchased with that money wage - it is the real wage that counts.  This maximizing behavior on either side of the market for labor gives us the demand curve for labor as an inverse function of the real wage and the supply curve as a direct function of the real wage.

The intersection of the supply and demand curves for labor determines the level of employment and the real wage and, one step removed, the level of aggregate output.  With a real wage of (W/P)1 in Figure 17-1, there is equilibrium between the supply of and demand for labor.  At this real wage, employers choose to hire N1 of labor and workers choose to provide N1 of labor.  With the aggregate production function of Part A, employment of N1 indicates aggregate output of O1.

In the classical scheme of things, any real wage other than (W/P)1 in a system of competitive markets will generate forces causing the real wage to rise or fall by the amount necessary to establish equilibrium in the labor market.  Assume, for example, that the real wage is (W/P)2, at which real wage the quantity of labor supplied is N3 and the quantity demanded is N2.  To achieve equilibrium there must be a fall in the real wage, and this may be accomplished by an appropriate decline in W, a rise in P, or some combination of the two.4  A fall in W follows from the excess of supply over demand for labor, which leads to competition among workers for jobs.  This causes workers to offer their services at a lower money wage, and a falling money wage, on the assumption

4. We will later see that adjustment could be brought about entirely by a rising price level, but since we have not yet worked into the analysis the classical theory of the determination of the price level, it is best at this point to assume a constant price level.

341

of a constant price level, means a falling real wage.  A falling real wage means that employers find it profitable to hire more labor (a movement down the demand curve) and that workers choose to supply less labor (a movement down the supply curve).  Once the money wage has fallen by the amount necessary to reduce the real wage from (W/P)2 to (W/P)1, equilibrium is reached.  Employment has risen from N2 to N1, and output has risen from O2 to O1.  If we had assumed instead an initial real wage below the equilibrium real wage, the adjustment process would be similar.  However, in this case there would bean excess demand for labor and competition among employers that would bid up the money wage by the amount necessary to raise the real wage to its equilibrium level.

The equilibrium level of employment so determined is also the full-employment leve1; that is, at this level all those who are able, willing, and seeking to work at prevailing wage rates are employed.  Since any other leve1 of employment is a disequilibrium level, a familiar proposition of classical theory is that the equilibrium position in the market for labor is necessarily one of full employment.  Whatever unemployment, apart from frictional unemployment, persists in the face of this equilibrium must be voluntary unemployment.  For example, with the equilibrium real wage established at (W/P)1, any persons who are unemployed are considered to be voluntarily unemployed if they are seeking work but will accept work only at a money wage that, at the existing price level, means a real wage greater than (W/P)1.  They are seeking a real wage that is inconsistent with the marginal productivity of their labor, and in effect they are “pricing” themselves out of the market.  Given our previous assumption of a constant price level, there is in the classical system no barrier to full employment or to the elimination of involuntary unemployment as long as labor is willing to reduce its money wage as required to produce that real wage at which all who wish to work will be hired.

342

 Index

A&E Homepage

next page