MACROECONOMICS +

3.0 Model

3.3 The Monetarist Model (cont'd)

(b) Demand for Money

(c) Theory of Nominal Income

(d) Policy Implications

(b) Demand for Money

The Monetarist Model begins with the Cambridge version of the “equation of exchange”:

(9.1)     Md = kPY where the demand for money is a function of ‘nominal income’, i.e. the P level times real income Y, and where k is the assumed ‘stable’ or constant proportion of nominal income held as cash.

Given that k was treated as a constant and the money supply M was exogenously determined by the monetary authority, the Cambridge equation could be expressed as a theory of nominal income:

(9.2)     M(1/k) = PY, or, alternatively as:

(9.3)     MV = PY where V is also assumed to be constant.

Keynes had assumed that assets or wealth (Wh) would held either in the form of cash money or other assets, specifically an homogeneous category called ‘bonds’, i.e. interest earning financial assets.  The key for Keynes in determining how much would be held as cash and how much as bonds was the interest rate.   Put another way, k would vary with the interest rate (r).  If  r rose the speculative demand for money would fall as would transactional demand.  If r fell the demand for cash would rise.  Given that k was now treated by Keynes as a variable rather than a constant the equation of exchange could not be used to generate a theory of nominal income.  It was this conclusion that the Monetarists contested.

The Monetarist (specifically Milton Friedman and his disciples) began by accepting Keynes’ assumption that Wh could be held either as cash or income earning assets.  However, they did not accept that there was an homogenous category of such other assets called ‘bonds’.   Rather they believed that:

(9.4)     Md = L(P, Y, rB, rE, rD) where r was the rate of return:

- on bonds (B) known as the interest rate;

- on equities or company shares (E) known as dividends plus capital gains; and,

- on durable goods including real estate, works of art and other physical assets (D) known as appreciation.

According to the Monetarists any increase in any one of the 3 types of r would result in a decline in the demand for money but would be offset by compensatory decreases in one or both of the other rates of return thereby keeping k stable.  For example, when the price of stock equity went up, the price of bonds would tend to go down.

Three differences can be drawn at this point between Keynes and the Monetarists:

a) for Keynes the demand for money was unstable because of changing ‘animal spirits’, i.e. investor confidence.  For the Monetarists, the demand for money was stable, implicitly because the increase in one kind of r would tend to be matched by a decrease in another;

b) for Keynes there were different types of demand for money: transactional, precautionary and speculative.  For the Monetarists, the demand for money was the demand for money as a useful assets and difference in the types of demand were not material; and,

c) for Keynes, Wh was composed of cash and a homogenous category of interest earning assets called bonds.  For the Monetarists, there were different rates of return for different ‘financial’ assets, e.g. bonds, equities and durable goods.

Restating the Cambridge equation, the Monetarist theory of money demand becomes:

(9.1’)    Md = k (rB, rE, rD) PY

where k is no longer a constant as in the Classical Model but rather a variable dependent on different rates of return.  An increase in any of them  will cause k to fall but overall they balance each other and k remains relatively stable.

For the Monetarist, equilibrium in the money market exists when:

(9.5)     M = Md k (rB, rE, rD) PY

Given the Monetarist assumption that the demand for money was stable an increase in the money supply would require either that PY rise or that rB, rE, rD fall causing k to rise.  To the degree that a change in the money supply results in a change in PY, to that degree, the quantity of money is important in determining nominal income.

(c) Theory of Nominal Income

As we have seen under the Cambridge equation with k as a constant and Ms fixed by the monetary authorities a theory of nominal income results with:

(9.6)     PY = (1/k) M, i.e., nominal income (PY) is equal to one over k times the money supply.

For the Monetarists, the other factors in equation 9.5 (rB, rE, rD) were assumed to have little effect on the demand for money approximating a constant, i.e. money or cash holdings (k) would be nearly constant.  The Monetarist view is shown in Fig. 9.3 where the LM curve is very inelastic reflecting the assumption that k is a near constant, i.e., the demand for money is relatively inelastic with respect to collective changes in rB, rE, rD .  By contrast, the IS curve is very interest rate elastic (gentle slope) reflecting the Monetarist assumption that aggregate demand is very sensitive to changes in interest rates.  This can be contrasted with the Keynesian Model in which LM is relatively interest elastic while IS is relatively interest rate inelastic (Fig. 9.2).   The LM and IS curves are, of course, shown assuming the price level is constant.  The Monetarist, on the hand, believed that the price level was variable.

The effect of the Monetarist assumptions – stable demand for money, interest inelasticity of demand for money, interest elasticity of investment and savings plus price level variability - on aggregate demand is shown in Fig 9.4 where an increase in the money supply results in an increase in Y and P.  In essence, the Monetarist position is that significant change in nominal income requires changes in the money supply.

Left unanswered is what determines the nature of the aggregate supply curve and therefore the effectiveness of changes in the money supply.

 

(d)  Policy Implications

The policy implications of the Monetarist Model for fiscal and monetary policy are quite different from the Keynesian Model.

i – Fiscal Policy

Assuming government increases G without raising T, it must finance the resulting deficit either by printing money or borrowing on financial markets (Fig. 9.5).  An increase in G shifts the IS curve up to the right.  Accepting the Monetarist position regarding the slope of the IS and LM curves then the shift in IS results in a relatively significant increase in the interest rate (r0 to r1) with a very slight increase in Y (Y0 to Y1).  In effect increase government borrowing raises the interest rate causing private investment to decline (crowding out) thereby minimizing the impact on Y of increased G.   This can be contrasted with the Keynesian Model shown in Fig. 9.1.

ii – Monetary Policy

To the Monetarist instability in Y resulted, not as in the Keynesian Model from instability of private investment, but rather from instability in the growth of the money supply.   Accordingly the best thing that the monetary authorities can do is to increase the money supply at a relatively steady rate, i.e., by a rule rather than at the discretion of policymakers.  Accepting the Monetarist assumptions about LM and IS, changes in the IS curve, e.g., increases in G or X, will have limited effect on Y but significant effects on r and P.  A stable increase in the money supply will mitigate inflationary pressure without introducing additional instability (Fig. 9.6).  Increases in the money supply also need to be stable because of imperfect knowledge about aggregate changes in the economy.  Thus given current theory and information it is not possible to accurately predict the future state of the economy and using discretionary monetary policy to significantly affect aggregate demand would introduce further instability into the system.  Thus the Monetarist position amounts to an effort to stabilize the economy rather than affect its growth.

The long and short of it is that the Monetarist Model calls for limited changes in fiscal policy because it only crowds out private investment and a steady rate of increase in the money supply to stabilize rather than manipulate economic growth.   The contrast with the Keynesian position is evident in Fig. 9.7.  In other words, like the Classical Model, the Monetarist Model calls for minimum government intervention in the economy.

 

 

 

previous page

next page