The Contribution of Art to National Income
Harry Hillman
Chartrand in Cultural
Economics '88: A Canadian Perspective Harry Hillman Chartrand,
William Hendon, Claire McCaughey (eds) Association for Cultural Economics
University of Akron, 1989, 31- |
|
Through history, the goods and services
that we buy, in which we invest and on which we pay taxes have changed. The total of these final demands on our
pocketbook is called National Expenditure. In symbolic logic, National Expenditure (Ye)
can be expressed as:
Ye
= f (C, I,
G) where C Consumption I = Investment G = Government. Similarly, through time, the means by
which we earn the income to consume, invest or pay taxes has come from a
changing set of factors of production including capital, labour
and technology. Taken together, these
income flows are called National Income. In symbolic logic (using the conventional
expression) National Income (Yi) can be expressed as: Yi = f
(K, L,T) where K = Capital L =
Labour T = Technology. Changes in the nature and mix of these
factors of production have generally involved crises in confidence concerning
previously accepted systems of economic thought (Keynes 1937). As will be demonstrated, however, the addition
of new factors of production to the National Income equation is, in a sense,
similar to Maslow’s Need Hierarchy. The new factor does not displace the old, but
rather creates a new margin for economic growth based upon a foundation
consisting of existing factors of production. In economics, National Expenditure and
Income represent an accounting identity. The one is exactly equal to the other, and are
said to be identical, or in symbolic logic:
Ye
= Yi = Y. From the 16th until the end of the 18th
century, it was accepted that only physical capital (K), e.g. gold, silver and
land, was productive of an economic surplus. Through re-investment of this surplus in
primary industries like farming, fishing and mining, it was believed that
national wealth would 31 increase. In fact,
these were considered the only productive sectors of the economy. In symbolic logic, the assumption that
National Income (Y) is a function of capital (K) is expressed:
Y= f (K). European conquest of the New World
appeared to confirm this view. The
English Pampheleteers and French economists Quesnay and Tourgot were the
dominant exponents of this theory of value (Schumpeter 1954). Today, these sectors make up what are called
the Primary Industries of the National Accounts. Monetarists and Gold Standard advocates
continue to echo, in one form or another, this ancient economic dogma of value. With respect to scientific knowledge, the
Royal Society was established in England in 1660 as a focus for the scientific
method. Technology during this period,
however, was essentially based on experiential knowledge developed by the
guilds. Scientific information was
symbolic of national wealth, i.e. a nation rich in gold could demonstrate its
wealth through pursuit of scientific knowledge. Similarly, Art was considered a symbol, not a
source of wealth: the idea of using art as a form of investment was unknown
in the eighteenth century... One bought paintings for pleasure, for status, for
commemoration, or to cover a hole in the ancestral panelling.
But one did not buy them in the expectation that they would make one richer
(Hughes, October 1984: 25). By the end of the 18th century, division
and specialization of labour (L) combined with
specialized industrial equipment (K) were accepted as productive of an economic
surplus, i.e.
Y
= f (K, L). Investment in manufacturing industries was
believed to increase national wealth. Smith, Ricardo, Malthus,
Marx and James Mill were the dominant theorists of this period (Barber 1967). The success of the United Kingdom in the
Industrial Revolution appeared to confirm this economic belief. Manufacturing constitutes the Secondary
Industries of contemporary National Accounts. Today some market economists believe that only
the manufacturing of physical goods is productive of an economic surplus. On the other hand, there are Marxists who
believe only the worker is productive. During
this Classical period, services including scientific research and the arts were
considered important social activities, but not productive of national wealth
(Barber 1967: 29). To a degree this scepticism
was justified because at the time major technological breakthroughs did not
result from organized university-based scientific research, but rather from the
experience of the individual inventor.
The men responsible for technological innovations ... during
the beginning of the Industrial Revolution were non-conformists who had been
excluded from the universities and learned their science indirectly while
pursuing their trade. In other words,
the coupling between science and technology was very loose and did not rely on
the established system of higher education (Senate Special Committee 1970: 21). By the mid- to late-l9th century, systemic
technological change (T) operating through perfectly competitive markets was
recognized as productive of an economic surplus. Investment in improving financial markets,
steam-powered transportation and enhanced communications such as the telegraph
was believed to increase national wealth, i.e.
Y
= f (K,L,T). The success of the United States in
developing a continental economy (Chandler 1962) appeared to confirm this
belief. The dominant theorists of this
period were John Stuart Mill and Alfred Lord Marshall (Mill 1848; Marshall
1890). This type of technology is called
disembodied technology, i.e. it does not refer to the application of a specific
item of scientific information in a specific product, but rather to general
systemic improvement in economic functions like transportation and
communications. Today, finance, transportation and
communications form part of the Tertiary Sector or Service Industries of the
National Accounts. During this
Neo-Classical period, government was generally considered an impediment rather
than a source of national wealth. This
was the period known as laissez-faire liberalism. Neo-conservatives who believe in setting
business free through deregulation and shrinking the power and reach of
government, accept this economic dogma of value With respect to scientific knowledge, it
was during this period in England that technology and the applied arts became
formalized in institutions of higher learning called polytechnics. The success of these institutions resulted
in their eventual absorption into the traditional universities where the pure
sciences and the scientific method combined with the applied sciences to
produce the pattern of scientific learning we know today. Furthermore, in 1870 compulsory primary
education was introduced in England which began the process of diffusing
scientific and experiential knowledge to a wider proportion of the population
than at any time in history. It is
important to note, however, that the major innovations of the period, e.g. the
telephone, 33 telegraph and electric light, did not result from
university-based research, but from the insight of independent inventors, who,
like Bell and Edison, created their own research institutes outside of the
university. During this Neo-Classical period,
works of art (including reproduction rights to paintings and drawings),
when sold through the emerging bourgeois art market, were considered a source
of national wealth. The emergence of
such reproduction rights reflected both the impact of new recording
technologies as well as the emergence of new economic institutions such as the
limited liability corporation (Hughes, October 1984). In fact, it was at the very time that the Arts
for Art’s Sake Movement (Henderson 1984: 46) withdrew from mainstream
industrial society in the 19th and 20th centuries, that
new communications media emerged. These
included the steel engraving plate followed by the photograph, sound recording,
motion picture, radio, television and video recording. These new technologies permitted the
industrialization of Art through commercial exploitation of revenue streams
implicit in copyright. In addition, the
commercial exploitation of these technologies by communications conglomerates
has resulted in the emergence of what is called commercial Popular Culture and
the eclipse of traditional folk art. The Great Depression of the 1930s
convinced most economists and policy-makers that the perfectly competitive
market was no longer the dominant form of industrial organization. Large scale industrial enterprise combined with
widespread unionization required Government’s active involvement to maintain
full employment and price stability in the face of imperfect markets. Therefore, from the mid-1930s until the
recessions of the late ‘70s and early ‘80s, Government (g) intervention was
considered necessary to assure growth in National Income, i.e. Y = f
(K,L,T) g Government fine-tuning of the economy and
counter-cyclical management of aggregate demand were considered critical in
assuring economic growth. As indicated
in the equation, however, Government was assumed not to generate wealth
directly, but rather to maintain and sustain its growth by assuring the
efficient interplay of capital, labour and
technology. Thus while tax cuts could
stimulate growth, growth resulted from the return of resources to the private
sector where improvements in the allocation and mix of capital, labour and technology were possible. In effect, the Government became recognized as
responsible for setting the rules of the game for economic behaviour. The role
of Government is recognized in the National Accounts as the Public Sector. Lord Keynes was the dominant theorist of this
period (Keynes 1936). Liberals and
social democrats committed to the active intervention of the State continue to hold this Keynesian economic
theory of value. During this Keynesian period of economic
thought, Art and Science were recognized as public
goods. It was accepted that if the
social benefits of an activity could not be fully captured by private producers
in the marketplace, then Government had a legitimate role in ensuring that an
appropriate quantity and quality were made available to the general public (Baumol, Bowen 1966). It was during this period that the
university and university-based research became the dominant source of new
technology including chemical, electrical and nuclear technologies. The war years confirmed that scientific
knowledge could serve a major role in the development of technology. During this period, the concept of
technological change evolved into embodied technological change, i.e.
specific items of scientific knowledge were embodied in a specific product,
e.g. the transistor radio. Conventional
wisdom held that the era of the independent, non-conformist inventor was
drawing to an end. However, this
convention could be quickly swept away by the appearance of another Bell,
Edison or Marconi. The success of the world economy from the
Second World War through the early ‘70s led most economists and politicians to
accept the Keynesian creed that
government intervention was the ultimate guarantor of growth and development. By the mid-’70s, however, stagflation,
recession, the oil crisis, and growth of public sector debt created a crisis of
confidence, a crisis predicted by Keynes himself. Today, various economic theories and dogma
compete for attention and acceptance. To
an extent, the 1980s are a time of Cultural Counter-Re formation in
which many strive to resuscitate values and beliefs swept away by the turbulent
cultural revolution of the 1960s, and the economic crises of the ‘70s and ‘80s.
This lack of confidence is similar to
contemporary architecture in which the certainties of the modern or
international style have been replaced by an eclecticism of design known as
Post-Modern Architecture. By analogy, we
have entered the era of Post-Modern Economics, an era without a generally
accepted dogma, an era in which we must begin again a long trek for economic
truth, understanding, and public confidence. At present, no single school of economic
thought enjoys general public confidence. Various new schools have, however, emerged in
recent years which share a belief that new factors of production have become
the source of economic growth. Such new
factors generally have been recognized through 35 re-definition of older concepts such as capital (K) and
technological change (T) (Wriston 1985). The importance of breaking out the
constituents of traditional technological change is evident when its
contribution to growth in National Income is considered.
Economists working in this area ... conclude that less
than one-third of the growth rate of output per worker over the years from the
turn of the century can be attributed to the rise in capital per worker. Over two-thirds of the growth rate of output
per worker has therefore to be attributed to all other factors covered by the
catchall called technological advance (Shapiro 1970; 493). Revision of the traditional concept of
technological change permits recognition of new factors of production
contributing to growth in National Income. From this revisionist perspective, technology,
as a factor of production in the National Income equation, has evolved from
disembodied to embodied to epistemological technological change, i.e.
changes and differences in the nature and sources of knowledge, specifically
the Physical and Social Sciences and Art. Advances in physical technology (T) result
from research in the Physical Sciences. In
the last several generations such research has resulted in creation of the
chemical, electrical, and nuclear industries. In this generation, such research has resulted
in creation of the electronic and bio-technology industries. It is generally accepted that this type of
technological change leads to growth in national wealth. To the best of the author’s knowledge,
however, there are no empirical studies that demonstrate a causal relationship
between investment in physical research and development and growth in National
Income. Theoretical and political belief
in the argument, however, is strong. Various
terms have been used to describe what, at any moment, is considered to be the
most efficient physical technology. The
term leading edge has been used. Similarly,
the term State of the Art has been applied. The ways in which workers and managers are
motivated and the ways in which they combine with financial capital, plant and
equipment to create business enterprise can be called Organizational Technology
(O). Advances in organizational
technology emerge from research and development in the social and management
sciences. Such advances lead to growth
in National Income and affect the capacity of a company or a country to
effectively innovate new products and processes. The economic impact of improved Organizational
Technology on national wealth has been estimated at 20 to 40% of the net
national product of the United States (Liebenstein
1981). The Economic
Council of Canada has also recognized the negative
consequences of poor organizational technology in Canada (Economic Council
1985). The phrase which has become the
touchstone for organizational success is In Search of Excellence. Just as the physical and social sciences
are the source of physical and organizational technological change, Art is the epistemologic source of improved product Design (D). Unlike the sciences, however, advances in Art
do not generally take place in the university but rather emerge from the
professional non-profit fine arts where art for art’s sake is the
dominant motivation (Chartrand 1987). The contribution that Design brings to the
marketplace can be called Elegance. This
term is also used in mathematics, the physical sciences and economics where it
expresses Occam’s Razor, a guiding principle of the scientific
method: Fewest assumptions for the maximum explanation. Elegance can be defined as “ingeniously
simple and effective” (Sykes 1985. 311) This also catches the sense of economy
as frugality. Aesthetic Design is fundamentally
different from technical or functional design such as a more fuel-efficient
automobile engine. Its impact on
consumer behaviour involves what has been called “the
best looking thing that works” (Cwi 1985). If a consumer does not like the way a product
looks, he or she may not try it. Similarly,
a rich endowment of natural resources does not guarantee a nation will develop up-scale
value-added products, e.g. Canada is the largest timber producing country in
the world and yet imports Swedish IKEA furniture. This is not because Swedish pine is better,
but rather due to superior design. The importance of Art to international economic
competitiveness was first recognized in the English-speaking world over 150
years ago in the United Kingdom with the establishment of the first school of
design in 1836. Until 1814, the Statute
of Artificers had regulated training and employment of artisans in the
craft guild tradition. In that year,
responding to deregulation or laissez-faire economic policies,
Parliament abolished the Statute. In
short order, the guild system collapsed and the labour
market became flooded with unskilled workers. By 1835 the quality of British production,
particularly textiles, had declined to the point that the British Board of
Trade appointed a Select Committee to investigate the problem and recommend
remedies. The Committee called for the
direct application of Art in manufacturing in order to maintain competitiveness
with European rivals. The result was
creation of schools of design (Savage 1985: 94-97). Similarly, in 1870, the Commonwealth of Massachusetts
became the first American State to make Art Education a requirement in the
public 37 schools with passage of the Drawing Act. The Act originated through pressure by
Boston manufacturers who argued that European students were trained in design
and drawing and therefore American manufacturers suffered a competitive
disadvantage (Freedman 1985: 21). Within
two decades, the same argument served to introduce art education in Canadian
schools (Chalmers 1985: 108). During
this period, the most eminent of contemporary economists, Alfred Lord Marshall,
explicitly recognized the importance of Art to economic life, even if he
questioned the moral results of art education.
Education in art stands on a somewhat different
footing from education in hard thinking: for while the latter nearly always
strengthens the character, the former not infrequently fails to do this. Nevertheless the development of the artistic
faculties of the people is in itself an aim of the very highest importance, and
is becoming a chief factor of industrial efficiency.... Increasingly wealth is
enabling people to buy things of all kinds to suit the fancy, with but a
secondary regard to their powers of wearing; so that in all kinds of clothing
and furniture it is every day more true that it is the pattern which sells the
things. (Marshall 1920: 177-178). Since the Great Depression of the 1930s,
however, the economic importance of design, and therefore the contribution of
Art to National lncome, has, in effect, been
forgotten. Partially this reflects the
perceived dubious morality of the artist reflected in Marshall’s words. It also reflects the pedagogic triumph of the Pestalozzian rationale for art education, i.e. to develop
creativity and expression, which displaced the economic rationale in the 1930s
(Betenas 1985: 99-101). It also reflects the traditional dis-ease concerning Art felt by political
philosophers since the time of Plato (Plato. The Republic.
Book X). It also reflects, however, a general
short-sightedness on the part of contemporary economists and other social
scientists concerning the nature and implications of the Industrial Revolution.
The Industrial Revolution not only
transformed economic production, it also transformed the nature of consumption
making phenomena like advertising, the department store, fashion and the mail
order catalogue critical to the modern economy (McCracken 1988: 4). This lack of study has resulted in little
empirical evidence concerning the impact of Art on economic competitiveness. But while the impact of improved Design has
not been quantified, its impact on competitiveness is again being recognized.
There is, then, another aspect to culture, namely good
taste, good design and creative innovation, that
should enable smaller industrial economies to compete effectively in the world
economy... In this endeavour, higher quality implies
an organic relationship between business and engineering, on the one hand, and
design and craftsmanship, on the other... High quality products, technologies,
plants, homes, cities and locales require the presence of creative artists of all kinds. To increase the long-run supply of artists...
governments must support the artists and the arts. The long-term return from investment in
artists and the arts is real and substantial. In the absence of strong public
support of this sector, Canada will not reap these benefits. Governments at all
levels should increase their contribution to their respective arts councils
(Royal Commission 1985:115-116). Today the importance of design in
international competitiveness can be seen in the United States and Canada where
higher quality consumer products tend to come from abroad, particularly from
Europe. Why? Given that capital plant and equipment in
North America is as good as that in Europe, the answer is not superior European
production technology. In fact, it
results from a feedback between skilled consumption and production resulting in
superior design (Scitovsky 1976). When the design advantage of European
producers, and increasingly that of Japanese producers of consumer electronics,
is combined with the wage advantage of offshore or Third World producers, then
the North American producer is left with a narrowing mid-range market. This combination of design and wage
disadvantages may explain the apparent de-industrialization of North America. Improved productivity through robotics and
other new technologies may lower costs of production, but only improved design
will secure for North American producers part of the growing up-scale consumer
market. The importance of enhanced design is
becoming apparent to some major North American corporations including SCM,
Teledyne, Black & Decker, and J.C. Penney. This change reflects a bottom-line awareness
that if a consumer does not like the way a product looks, then he or she may
never get close enough to find out how well it performs, and therefore there is
no chance for a sale. Growing awareness
of this basic principle is resulting in increased recognition of the importance
of industrial design and the role it plays in helping companies meet sales and
marketing goals. More and more marketers
are now enlisting the aid of design consulting companies or setting up their
own in-house design departments (Skolnik October
1985: 46). From where do design skills
come? They come from the practice of
Art. Changes in physical technology resulting
from research in the physical sciences (T), improvements in organizational
technology (O) resulting from social and management science research, and
improvements in design (D) resulting from advances in the Arts (Shapiro 1970:
495) are now major sources of growth in National Income, i.e.
Y = f (K,L,T,O,D) g.
39 Advances in physical, organizational and
design technology are legally protected by intellectual property rights
legislation including: patents (emerging from the physical sciences); registered
industrial design (emerging from the physical sciences and the arts); trademarks
(emerging from the arts), and copyright (emerging from the physical
and social sciences, humanities and the arts). Managerial and industrial know-how also
falls into this category of abstract goods and services. At present such abstract goods and services
constitute what can be called the Quaternary or Fourth Sector of the
economy. At any point in time, there exists a stock
of capital and labour which embodies current and past
technical and educational attainment. Advances
in physical, organizational and design technologies are flows that become
embodied in new products, industrial processes and equipment, organizational
methods, styles and fashions. In dollar terms, research, both scientific
and artistic, involves a tiny amount of resources compared to the existing
capital stock and labour force. However, its role in economic growth is that
of a catalyst stimulating changes and improvements in the quality and
efficiency of capital and labour (Shapiro 1970:
490-91). The Information Economy is
based on the buying, selling and licensing of abstract intellectual property
rights which result from advances in physical, organizational and design
technologies. In this paper the changing nature and
definition of National Income has been explored. This involved inclusion of progressively more
abstract concepts of National Income. The
examination began in the 16th century with a definition restricted to bullion
and land. This definition had evolved by
the end of the 18th century to include capital plant, equipment and the
division of labour. In the 19th century, improvements in
communications and transportation within a competitive marketplace became
accepted as a source of growth in National Income. By the middle of the 20th century, the role of
Government as regulator of economic activity was recognized. Today, advances in the Physical and Social
Science and Art also contribute to growth in National Income. Such advances are legally embodied in
intellectual property legislation such as patents, copyright, registered
industrial design and trademarks. The buying, selling and licensing of these rights make-up the
Quaternary Sector of the Post-Modern Economy. Within this Quaternary Sector, Art contributes
elegance in advertising, marketing and product design, particularly in the
growing up-scale consumer goods marketplace.
Research Director, The Canada Council
Barber,
W.J., A
History of Economic Thought, Penguin Books, Harmondsworth,
United Kingdom, 1967.
Baumol,
W., W. Bowen, The Performing Arts: The
Economic Dilemma, Twentieth Century Fund, New York City 1966.
Bell,
D., The
Cultural Contradictions of Capitalism, Basic Books, NY, 1976.
Betenas,
E., Is There an Ideal Model for Arts Education?, in
Wilson B, H. Hoffa (eds), The History of Art Education: Proceedings from the
Penn State Conference, Pennsylvania State University, 1985.
Boulding,
K.E., Placing a Value on the Arts, Keynote Address at the 1986, World
Conference on Arts, Politics, and Business, University of British Columbia,
Vancouver, July 22, 1986.
Chalmers,
F.G., South Kensington and the Colonies II: The Influence of Walter Smith in
Canada, in Wilson B, H. Hoffa (eds), The History
of Art Education: Proceedings from the Penn State Conference, Pennsylvania
State University, 1985.
Chandler,
A., Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of American Industrial
Enterprise, MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1962.
Chartrand,
H.H., Social Science and
Humanities Research Impact Indicators, Futures, Ottawa, 1980.
Chartrand,
H.H., An Economic Impact Assessment of the Canadian Fine Arts, in The Economics of Cultural Industries,
Association of Cultural Economics, University of Akron, 1984.
Chartrand,
H.H., Cultural Economics of Arts Funding: Five Variations on a Theme,
Introduction to Paying for the Arts, Chartrand,
Hendon, Horowitz (eds.), University of Akron, 1987.
Cwi, D.,
suggested in conversation with the author, Cultural Policy Institute, Baltimore,
November 1985.
Economic
Council of Canada, The Bottom Line, Ottawa,
1983.
Freedman,
K., “Art Education and the Development of the Academy: The Ideological Origins
of Curriculum Theory,” in Wilson B, H. Hoffa (eds), The History of Art Education:
Proceedings from the Penn State Conference, Pennsylvania State University,
1985.
Ginzberg,
E., G. Vojta, “The Service Sector of the U.S.
Economy,” Scientific American, March 1981.
Henderson,
J.L., Cultural Attitudes in
Psychological Perspective, Inner City Books, Toronto, 1984.
Hughes,
R., “Art and Money: Part I,” New Art Examiner, October 1984.
Innis, HA., Empire and Communication, University of Toronto
Press, Toronto, 1950. 41
Keynes,
M., The
General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (1936), Macmillan, London,
1949.
Keynes,
M., “To the QJE from Chapter 12 of the General Theory,” Quarterly Journal of
Economics, February 1937.
Liebenstein,
H., “Microeconomics and X-Efficiency Theory: If there is no crisis there ought
to be one,” in Crisis in Economic Theory, D. Bell, I. Kristol (eds),
Basic Books, NY, 1981.
Marshall,
A., Principles of Economics
8th Edition, (1920: 1st edition 1890) English Language Book Society London,
1969.
McCracken,
G., Culture and Consumption: New Approaches to the Symbolic Character of
Consumer Goods and Services, Indiana University Press, Bloomington,
1988.
Mill,
J.S., ,Principles of Political Economy with
Some of Their Applications to Social Philosophy, London, 1848.
Plato,
The Republic Book X, in Great Books
of the Western World, Encyclopedia Britannica, Chicago 1952.
Porat,
MU., The Information Economy, US Department of Commerce, Washington, DC,
1977.
Research
and Evaluation, Selected Arts Research Statistics, 7th Edition, The Canada Council, December 1987.
Royal
Commission on the Economic Union and Development Prospect for Canada, Report:
Volume II, Minister of Supply and Services, Ottawa, Canada, 1985.
Savage,
L., The History of Art Education and Social History: Text and Context in a British
Case of Art School History, in Wilson B, H. Hoffa (eds),
The History of Art Education: Proceedings from the Penn State Conference,
Pennsylvania State University, 1985.
Schumpeter-,
J.A., History of Economic Analysis, (1954) Oxford University Press, NY,
1968
Scitovsky,
T., The Joyless Economy, Oxford
University Press, London, 1976
Senate
Special Committee on Science Policy, A Science Policy for Canada, Volume
1, the Queen’s Printer, Ottawa, 1970.
Shapiro, E., Macroeconomic Analysis, Harcourt,
Brace & World, NY, 1970.
Skolnik,
R., “The Rise and Rise of Product Design,” Sales and Marketing Management, Oct.
7, 1985.
Sykes,
J.B., The
Concise Oxford Dictionary of Current English, Oxford University Press,
Oxford, 1985. Wriston, W.B., “Gnomons, Words and
Politics,” The Executive Club, Chicago, 1985. |