The Competitiveness of Nations in a Global Knowledge-Based Economy
Leonard M. Dudley †
Space, Time, Number:
Harold A. Innis As Evolutionary Theorist
Canadian Journal of Economics,
28 (4a)
Nov. 1995, 754-769.
What causes economic change? Traditionally, economists have answered that
the explanation lies in exogenous shocks to technology, factor stocks, or
preferences. In the last half-decade of
his career, the Canadian economic historian Harold Innis
(1894-1952) proposed an alternative approach - a theory of endogenous change in
communications technology. He argued
that the principal developments in western social history could be explained
by a process of alternation between media biased towards conservation of
information over time and those biased towards transmission over distance. This
paper demonstrates the close parallels between the concepts used by Innis and contemporary theories of social evolution. It
also indicates the importance for future research of his vision of
communications media as the most fundamental of enabling technologies.
† Université de Montréal
Harold A. Innis Memorial
Lecture presented at the Canadian Economics Association meetings, Université du Québec a Montréal,
Montreal, 2 June 1995. The author thanks
Pierre Fortin, Michael Huberman, Bentley MacLeod, and
Francois Vaillancourt for their helpful comments and
encouragement.
754
What do Innocent III (1160-1216)
and William Henry Gates III (1955- ) have in common other than the same roman numeral after their names? At first glance, very little: the first was a
mediaeval pope; the second is chief executive officer of a contemporary
computer software firm. However, there
are striking parallels in their careers. Both dropped out of college as young men and
went on to become the leaders of powerful organizations specialized in information
processing. Both did so by exploiting
new technologies that reduced the cost of storing information for elite groups
within their societies. And the
contributions of both point to serious limitations in neoclassical general
equilibrium theory.
The problem is to interpret
economic change. Traditionally,
economists have explained changes in the price system by exogenous shocks,
either to preferences, to factor endowments, or to technology. Given such a shock, neoclassical theory is
able to predict its consequences for quantities and prices. Yet if examined closely,
most of such shocks turn out to be new ideas, whether new fashions and customs,
new attitudes to working and saving, or new ways of combining production
factors. Unless an economic theory
provides an explanation for how ideas originate, how they are diffused, and how
they are selected, it is incomplete. In
this sense, the neoclassical heritage is unable to cope with the careers of
Innocent III and Bill Gates. [1]
Yet, I shall argue, changes
such as the transformation of mediaeval Europe under popes like Innocent III
and the current profound restructuring of industrial societies at the hands of
software entrepreneurs like Bill Gates are explained, and indeed predicted, in
the writings of the Canadian economic historian Harold A. Innis.
During a remarkable half-decade of
research between 1945 and 1950, Innis found what he
believed to be a recurrent pattern in western social history. He expressed his ideas in such enigmatic, even
oracular, fashion, however, that readers of his own day and since have had
difficulty understanding them. As
Marshall McLuhan later wrote, Innis’s
writing in this period is compressed into a ‘mosaic structure of seemingly
unrelated sentences and aphorisms’ (McLuhan 1964,
vii). Three samples (with italics added)
will suffice to give the flavour of his style. ‘[The introduction of monopolistic elements in
culture] is accompanied by... collapse in the face of technological change
which has taken place in marginal regions’ (1951, 4). ‘The tenacity of the Byzantine empire assumed
the achievement of a balance which recognized the role of space and
time’ (1950, 167). ‘The relative
emphasis on time or space will imply a bias of significance to the
culture in which [a medium of communication] is imbedded’ (1951, 33). ‘Marginal regions,’ ‘balance,’ and ‘bias’: what
does Innis mean? These quotations are taken from three lectures
that Innis gave in 1947 at Laval University, in 1948
at Oxford University, and in 1949 at the
1. Lucas (1988) and Romer (1986, 1990) have
been among the most innovative in addressing the problem of endogenizing
technical change within the neoclassical model, allowing progress to depend on
the stock of accumulated knowledge.
University of Michigan. In each case, Innis’s method was to look for patterns in the historical
flows of names, events, and dates. Although
there were no equations or logical proofs in his writing, he did, I shall
argue, have a theory. To understand Innis’s ideas, however, we must decode the rather special
vocabulary with which he expressed his thoughts. In doing so, we shall compare Innis’s theory with the generalized Darwinian model of
evolution as defined by the American psychologist, Donald T. Campbell (1965,
27). [2] In addition, we shall explore the links
between Innis’s ideas and the essential elements of
recent evolutionary modelling in economics, as set
out by the German economist Ulrich Witt (1991). [3] Finally, we shall examine Innis’s
theory of communications as the key to a new approach for modelling
technological change.
In the late 1940s and
1950s, Harold A. Innis was perhaps Canada’s leading
scholar. He was the author of three
well-received studies on Canadian economic history, A History of the
Canadian Pacific Railway (1923), The Fur Trade in Canada (1930), and
The Cod Fisheries (1940). In each
book, Innis examined how changes in the techniques
for producing primary products - staples - affected patterns of social organization
over long periods of time in regions on the periphery of European civilization.
He was head of the Department of
Political Economy at the University of Toronto and was first dean of the
graduate school of that university. As a
sign of international recognition, he was elected president of the American
Economic Association.
In 1945, immediately
following the Second World War, Innis was invited to
visit the Soviet Union. He was fifty
years old at that time, and the journey marked a turning point in his thinking.
It was a shock for him to witness the
accomplishment of a structure of social organization so completely different
from the market system that he had studied in detail. In a letter, he wrote: ‘I felt the necessity
for a much broader approach in economic history and the very great danger of a
very narrow approach such as we seem to get nothing else but’ (Creighton
1957/1978, 122).
The opportunity to deliver
a more general message to a wider audience came the following year. In May 1946 Innis
was elected president of the Royal Society of Canada, an interdisciplinary
group of leading Canadian researchers. The
position required that he deliver a presidential address the following year. It was about this time that Innis began to put together what we might today call a set
of hypertext files. They were
cross-referenced index cards on which Innis noted his
ideas as they came to him. [4]
2. Durham (1991) reviews the development of Darwinian theories in
anthropology.
3. Robson (1995) applies an evolutionary model to explain
attitudes towards risk in economics; Carmichael and MacLeod (1994) suggest that
social customs may be modelled with biological
models; Paquet (1995) surveys theories of
institutional evolution.
4. These notes were subsequently sorted and published by Christian
(1980).
756
Innis presented a first version of his broader approach to
economic history in May 1947 in Quebec City in a lecture entitled, ‘Minerva’s
owl’ (1951, chap. 1). The theme of his
study was the diffusion of new technologies - how the use of an innovation
spreads over time. This subject had been
discussed in brilliant fashion in the recent writings of Joseph Schumpeter, who
explained cyclical changes in output by the impact of innovations. In Capitalism,
Socialism and Democracy (1942), the Austrian economist had argued that the
principal source of contemporary economic innovation was the large-scale
corporation, which alone had the capacity to coordinate research and the
resources to apply new technologies.
Innis’s ideas were sharply different from those of
Schumpeter. Instead of dealing with new
technologies in production and transportation, Innis
focused on new communications media. Rather
than limit himself to markets for goods and services, he enlarged his scope to
cover the overall pattern of interaction within the society. Instead of concentrating on the monopolistic
structures at the centre, he directed his attention to the competitive fringe,
the contesting forces on the geographic periphery.
The question that Innis asked his Quebec audience was the following. If the dominant group within an organization
derives its power from a monopoly of the existing communications technology,
how can an alternative form of communication with different characteristics
possibly spread? Taking issue with
Schumpeter, he argued that it is not in the interest of the group that holds
power to encourage innovation. Indeed,
he went on, those who hold a monopoly of knowledge will actively resist the
introduction of new techniques. He
quoted Albert Guérard: ‘To the founder of a school,
everything may be forgiven except his school’ (1951, 4). As a result, a new technology can spread only
in marginal regions where the dominant elite’s power is weak. ‘In the regions to which Minerva’s owl takes
flight the success of organized force may permit a new enthusiasm and an
intense flowering of culture incidental to the migration of scholars engaged in
Herculean efforts in a declining civilization to a new area with possibilities
of protection’ (1951, 5).
As in most of his last
works, Innis’s style was that of theme and historical
variations, with very little in the way of recapitulation. After a brief introduction written in this
dense, epigrammatic style, Innis proceeded to a long
series of historical case studies. One
of the most interesting of these examples concerns the spread of parchment,
along with a new script and a standardized written vehicular language, in early
mediaeval Europe. Parchment, a writing
material made from the skins of animals, was discovered about 200 BC. Until the eighth century, however, the
preferred medium for administrative purposes was papyrus, a kind of paper made
from reeds.
Within the Christian
Church, a monastic movement had begun by the fourth century. Under the later Roman emperors and their
Byzantine and Germanic successors, the monasteries remained under centralized
control. Only on the fringes of the
former Roman Empire, in Ireland and subsequently in England, did the monasteries
acquire a certain degree of autonomy. Here
the abbots took the initiative of having existing works from throughout
Christendom transcribed onto parchment.
With the Arab conquest of
much of the Mediterranean basin in the seventh and eighth centuries, supplies
of papyrus to western Europe were cut to a bare
trickle. Since papyrus decomposes within
about three generations, virtually the only knowledge retained was that
transferred to much more durable parchment by monks. The parchment codex manuscripts in the
libraries of English monasteries therefore became a principal repository of
European learning. From England St
Boniface (675-754) was sent out to convert the pagan German tribes,
introducing Latin on parchment into central Europe. Another Anglo-Saxon churchperson, Alcuin (735-804), was the principal adviser to Charlemagne
and the author of reforms that standardized Latin culture across western Europe
(ibid., 14-17). Innis described how
the ‘clear, precise, and simple’ Carolingian minuscule, developed under Alcuin at the court of Charlemagne, gradually spread
throughout western Europe.
In this example, Innis was explaining how a new communications medium,
standardized Latin as a vehicular language in a new script on a new material,
gradually spread from the British Isles throughout northern Europe. In essence, the new idea was carried from
monastery to monastery from the periphery to the centre, successfully
replicating itself in each new host institution.
Is there a more general
process involved? In an essay on
theories of cultural evolution published in 1965, Donald T. Campbell set out
the criteria that a Darwinian model of evolution must satisfy. One of them is ‘a mechanism for the preservation,
duplication, or propagation of... variants’ (1965, 27). Innis’s concept of
the margin, by which a new communications technique establishes a foothold in
an isolated region, successfully reproduces itself, and eventually challenges
the dominant medium, would appear to satisfy this criterion. Indeed, the suggested mechanism is quite
similar to that proposed by biologists to explain the emergence of new species
(see, e.g., Dawkins 1986).
Why should Innis’s approach be of interest to economists? The economic analogue to the biological
concept of reproduction is the process of technological diffusion. Witt (1991, 91-6) points out that the basic
principle in evolutionary models of diffusion is what is called the
frequency-dependency effect. Each individual
in a population must decide whether or not to adopt a new technique. The probability that she adopts, however, will
be a function of the number of members of the population who have already
adopted it. In the mediaeval case, monks
travelling slowly from one monastery to another were
the principal means of diffusion. The
greater the number of monasteries that had already adopted the technology, the
more likely a non-adopter was to receive a visit from converts to the
innovation. In any given sub-population
of monasteries, however, some threshold may have been required before the new
technique was adopted.
In short, in this essay Innis took the first step towards the construction of an
evolutionary model of social change. His
theory was still incomplete, but already Innis had
left his audience of the Royal Society of Canada far behind. His biographer, the historian Donald
Creighton, wrote that his lecture, ‘Minerva’s owl,’ was ‘much too long’ and
that ‘many in his audience were puzzled or bewildered’ (1957, 127).
758
In June 1946, a month after
his election as president of the Royal Society of Canada, Innis
had received an invitation from the administrators of the Beit
Fund of Oxford University. They asked
him to deliver six lectures ‘on any subject in the economic history of the
British Empire,’ undoubtedly expecting him to write on the economic relations
of colonial regions like Canada to the imperial centre in Britain (Creighton
1957, 126). Over the next two years, Innis did indeed prepare six lectures for an international
audience. The context of these lectures
was by no means confined to a single subject, however, nor did he limit his
attention to economic phenomena; most strikingly, his talks had little to do
with the British Empire.
Innis began the Beit Lectures on
12 May 1948 at All Souls College. He
warned his listeners at the outset that a slight digression might be necessary.
‘I shall attempt to outline the
significance of communication in a small number of empires as a means of
understanding its role in a general sense and as a background to an
appreciation of its significance to the British Empire.’ Six lectures, later, this slight digression to
look at a small number of empires turned out to have been a new theory of
historical change.
We have seen that the first
of Innis’s concepts, the margin, proposed a process
of technological diffusion. The question
that he now addressed was whether or not this process attained an equilibrium and if so, whether two or more technologies
would coexist in such a state. [5] For each communications medium, Innis
asserted, there will be a corresponding form of social organization. Some media will favour
decentralization, while others will favour centralization.
Balance is reached when the centrifugal
forces of the former are exactly offset by the centripetal forces of the
latter. ‘Large-scale political
organizations such as empires... have tended to flourish under conditions in
which civilization reflects the influence of more than one medium’ (1950, 7). It is in such a situation, Innis
felt, that social welfare will be highest. We have seen that he noted approvingly the
balance between what he referred to as time and space in the Byzantine Empire.
A more likely outcome was
for one medium to dominate the others. Such a monopoly situation would then lead to
rigidity and decay. ‘We can perhaps
assume that the use of a medium of communication over a long period will
eventually create a civilization in which life and flexibility will become
exceedingly difficult to maintain’ (ibid., 34).
It was such failure to
achieve balance, Innis argued, that led to the
political instability characteristic of the west in pre-modern times. Innis devoted an
entire lecture in his Oxford series to mediaeval Europe. Under the papyrus and stylus medium of the
Roman Empire at its height, Europe was administered from a central point. But under the parchment and pen medium that
succeeded it, power was decentralized. The
hierarchic structures of empire were replaced by networks
5. In terms of evolutionary theory, does the process of replication lead
to an evolutionarily stable equilibrium in which mutant replicators
are eliminated? If so, is that
equilibrium polymorphic, that is, characterized by more than one replicator? See Binmore (1992, 422-9).
of monasteries and their secular overlords. ‘In contrast with papyrus, which was produced
in a restricted area under centralized control to meet the demands of a centralized
bureaucratic administration and which was largely limited by its fragile
character to water navigation, parchment was the product of a widely scattered
agricultural economy suited to the demands of a decentralized administration
and to land transportation’ (ibid., 140).
In western
Europe, a brief period of balance between the state with its tendency towards
centralization and religion with its generally decentralized structure was
achieved during the Carolingian renaissance from 768-814. After Charlemagne’s reign, however, the empire
of the Franks broke up into competing states, the basis of the modern nations
of Europe. By the thirteenth century the
papacy under leaders like Innocent III had managed to impose its authority over
the secular rulers of these successor states, including Frederick II, the Holy
Roman Emperor. ‘A civilization dominated
by parchment as a medium developed its monopoly of knowledge through
monasticism. The power of the Church was
reflected in its success in the struggle with Frederick II’ (ibid.,
165).
What is the process by
which one medium and its associated form of social organization are replaced by
another medium and an alternative social structure? For Innis, one
mechanism was competition for territory between states. For example, even though it was much smaller
in territory than the Roman Empire, the kingdom of Charlemagne was too large to
survive external predation. ‘Attacks
from the Danes and the Magyars accentuated local organizations of force and
separatist tendencies’ (ibid., 149). A second mechanism was competition between
centre and periphery for popular support within a given society. ‘ The monopoly of knowledge which had been built up invited
competition from a new medium of communication which appeared on the fringes of
western European culture and was available to meet the demands of lower strata
of society’ (ibid.).
In short, a system that is
more successful than another in feeding and protecting the majority of its
adherents will tend to be selected. This
process by which competition between systems results in retention of one way of
life and elimination of the other in Innis’s theory
therefore satisfies the second of the requirements set out by Campbell for a
Darwinian model of evolution; namely, ‘consistent selection criteria’ (1965,
27). A struggle for survival among
states and among groups within states weeds out less successful forms of
organization.
Innis’s idea of balance should be distinguished from the
concept of equilibrium in neoclassical economic theory. As Witt (1991, 96-8) has remarked,
neoclassical general equilibrium theory takes a strong position on the issue of
social coordination, proposing that an economic system converges to a state of
perfect coordination - equilibrium. All
firms in an industry, for example, will use the identical production
technology. For an evolutionary
approach, it is necessary to introduce the de-coordinating force of innovative
activity. To survive, agents must keep
within the moving bounds set by coordinating forces of markets and the
de-coordinating forces of innovation.
By these standards, Innis’s theory is clearly evolutionary. At any moment in a given society, different
communications technologies are likely to coexist. Indeed,
760
his ideal is a state of balance in which two or more
media of communication are used. Such a
state of balance is likely to be temporary, Innis
realizes, since one technology will tend eventually to dominate the other. Even then, however, there is no enduring
equilibrium, since, as we have seen, the monopoly position of the dominant
technology induces de-coordinating innovative activity.
Once again, Innis had raced far ahead of his audience. The reception of the six Oxford lectures also
was disappointing. ‘Innis’s most comprehensive and original thesis was
presented prematurely, too briefly and without the [necessary] vast mass of
supporting evidence and illustrative material’ (Creighton 1957, 135). Yet he had accomplished the essential. In his two years of research, Innis had acquired a mastery of the historical details of
social change. He could now add the
third and crucial element to his theory.
During the winter of 1948-9,
while Innis was finishing the revisions to his Oxford
lectures, to be published as Empire and Communications (1950), he
received an invitation to participate in a Royal Commission on Transportation
headed by W.F. Turgeon. The gruelling task
would consume much of his energy over the following two years. But before becoming involved in the
preparations for the Commission’s hearings, Innis
took the time to prepare an essay, ‘The bias of communications,’ which he
delivered at the University of Michigan in April 1949. The result was a synthesis of the two previous
studies and his most complete explanation of the process of historical change.
Perhaps the most difficult
of all problems in economic theory is to explain how new ideas arise. To deal with this problem, Innis
used the concept of bias. [6] Here Innis was dealing with the direction
of technical change. He was not, as
one might expect, referring to whether capital or labour
is saved, but rather to whether an innovation is designed to allow knowledge to
be transmitted more efficiently over space or to be preserved more effectively
over time. ‘According to its
characteristics [a medium of communication] may be better suited to the
dissemination of knowledge over time than over space, particularly if the
medium is heavy and durable and not suited to transportation, or to the
dissemination of knowledge over space than over time, particularly if the
medium is light and easily transported’ (1951, 33). Innis suggested that
both the direction and the rate of change are endogenously determined. ‘Monopolies or oligopolies of knowledge have
been built up in relation to the demands of force chiefly on the defensive, but
improved technology has strengthened the position of force on the offensive and
compelled realignments favouring the vernacular’
(ibid., 32). In other words, the elite
group that dominates the old technology will receive a monopoly rent from its
position. However, the high price for
information will encourage the development
6. Innis also used the notion of bias in the
introduction to Empire and Communications (1950, 7). The idea that the bias of
the dominant medium leads to innovation to correct the bias, however, is expressed
most clearly and consistently in the 1949 paper (1951, 34, 38, 40, 48, 49, 50,
60).
of a new technology with different characteristics,
intended to lower the cost of knowledge to the rest of the society.
An example from the
mediaeval period illustrates this concept of bias and its significance. The communications medium of the Roman Empire,
light but perishable papyrus, encouraged an excessive concern for territory;
that is, space. In the eighth century
the Arab conquest of the south shore of the Mediterranean Sea drove up the
price of papyrus to western Europe. The Carolingian monks were therefore forced to
turn to an alternative medium, parchment, which was heavier but much more
durable. Combining parchment with a new
standardized script, the Carolingian minuscule, they developed a powerful new
communications medium. As a result, over
the following centuries the previous bias towards extension over space was
replaced by a bias towards duration over time. The military-administrative bureaucracies of
the Roman Empire and its successor states were replaced by the religious bureaucracies
of the high middle ages (ibid., 48-50).
In proposing a process of
directed endogenous technological change, Innis was
taking a position sharply at variance with neoclassical economics, which has
considered technology to be exogenous. However,
he was offering the final component of an entirely different approach to social
organization. The third of Campbell’s
criteria for a Darwinian model of evolution is the ‘occurrence of variations’
(1965, 27). Innis’s
concept of bias, by which monopoly pricing generates new technology with
characteristics different from the old, clearly fits this requirement.
Innis went beyond the Darwinian model. The mutations in technology he described are
not the results of a random process. Rather, they are a reaction to price data. Innovations seem to be generated by what Witt
(1991, 89) calls a ‘satisficing’ mechanism in which
action arises from dissatisfaction with the current outcome. If so, Innis was
going beyond the evolutionary theory of his contemporary, Schumpeter, who had
little to say about how new ideas arise (Freeman 1990, 22). He was proposing the key element of a theory
of social change, namely, a model of cultural evolution.
There is no indication in
Creighton’s biography of how his American audience reacted to this
presentation. Together with Innis’s 1947 Royal Society address and several other
essays, the Michigan lecture was published in 1951 as a book,
The Bias of
Communication.
V. A Bumper-Car Theory of History
A popular ride in amusement
parks of the early postwar decades was the electric bumper car. By pressing on a pedal, the rider caused the
car to move at a fixed velocity until it hit an obstacle - either the bumper of
another car or the barrier around the concession. The vehicle then changed direction until it
hit some other obstacle. Innis’s theory of social change somewhat resembles this
amusement. The position of the vehicle
represents the nature of communications technology. As for the car, it represents social
institutions, and the rider, the population of the society, each carried along
by the momentum of technological change.
The bumpers are
762
the limits to the price of storing information over time
as opposed to the price of transmitting it over distance. At these limits there is a redirection of
society’s resources to search for an alternative communications medium.
Innis’s theory of history, as told in condensed form in his essay, ‘The bias of communication’ (1951, 33-60), may be illustrated with the help of figure 1.
Here, the ratio of the cost
of information storage to the cost of information transmission is measured on
the vertical axis, while the year is measured on the horizontal axis. In the prehistoric period, as information
accumulated with a fixed memory capacity for each individual, the marginal cost
of storing a unit of information reached the upper limit. In Mesopotamia, a way was found of storing
information by means of pictograms on clay tablets. Subsequently, phonetic writing developed,
using the same materials. The first
civilizations, ruled by a priestly caste, were concerned with time.
The information monopoly of
the ruling elites encouraged the search for alternative media. With the development of papyrus, it became
possible to send information efficiently over long distances. The cost of transmission was further reduced
when the west-Semitic peoples developed a consonantal alphabet capable of
representing human speech with two dozen characters. Using certain of these symbols for vowels, the
Greeks and Romans developed complete alphabets and came to dominate all of the
lands in the Mediterranean basin. Secular
rulers with codes of written law now emphasized the control of space.
Since papyrus crumbled
after three generations, it was not suitable for conserving information over
long periods. In the early Christian
era, the development of durable parchment, which could be bound into easily
consultable books provided
an alternative means of communication. When Arab conquests caused the price of
papyrus to rise in the seventh and eighth centuries, western
Europe switched to parchment and developed a standardized efficient Latin script.
European society of the middle ages was dominated by a religious elite, literate in
this vehicular medium and concerned with the preservation of knowledge over
time.
From the fourteenth century
on, the high cost of sending information over space encouraged the European
production of paper, an invention borrowed from the Chinese. Once again, a lighter, perishable medium was
being substituted for a heavier, durable one. In the fifteenth century the high price of
hand-copied manuscripts provided an incentive to experiment with mechanical
methods of reproducing information. The
resulting fall in transmission costs led to the development of written forms of
vernacular languages and intense competition for territory. In the nineteenth century the invention of
newsprint and steam and electric presses further marked the transition to media
adapted to the control of space. In the
twentieth century radio continued this trend towards an obsession with the
present.
We are now nearing the
moment when Innis’s career itself came to an end. What might he have predicted for the remainder
of the twentieth century? Applying the
model of figure 1, he might well have suspected that after some seven centuries
of preoccupation with space, the bumper car should hit the upper limit of the
ratio of storage of transmission costs. Accordingly,
innovation to reduce storage costs would be induced. The consequence would be a new concern for
time and difficulties with any existing institutions committed to the control
of space.
Applying this reasoning, Innis might have predicted fiscal problems for existing
territorial states. Difficulty in
maintaining cohesion might be particularly severe for states like the Soviet
Union, which had hitherto neglected the time dimension or for states like
Yugoslavia and Canada in which relatively homogeneous regions had different
concepts of time. In addition, Innis might have foreseen additional strength for movements
within individual societies devoted to furthering moral values. This is exactly the pattern that has been
observed in the industrialized world since the introduction of a powerful new
device for storing information, the integrated circuit, a
decade after Innis’s death. [7] Bill Gates is one of those who have recognized its
revolutionary implications. It is the
same pattern found in the history of mediaeval Europe after the death of
Charlemagne. Indeed to foresee where we
might be headed, we might do well to study the career of Innocent III, who was
not even an ordained priest when elected pope at the age of thirty-seven yet
went on to reshape European society.
VI.
The Missing Dimension: Number
It might be argued that it
is absurd to attempt to fit all of western social history within a simple,
two-dimensional view of communications technology as agent of social change. Indeed, the strongest arguments against the
time-space bumper-car
7. For more on this new technology and its effects on patterns of social
organization, see Dudley (1991, chap. 8).
764
model of the preceding section were provided by Innis himself. In
the introduction to one of his last essays, ‘The problem of space,’ he briefly
mentioned an additional concept that he placed on the same level as time and
space, namely, number. ‘Gauss held that
whereas number was a product of the mind, space had a reality outside
the mind whose laws cannot be described a
priori. In the history of thought,
especially of mathematics, Cassirer remarked, “at
times, the concept of space, at other times, the concept of numbers, took
the lead”’(1951, 92; italics added).
Could number be considered
a third dimension to communications technology? If so, how might this concept fit into the
structure that Innis designed to model space and
time? At issue, Innis
realized, is the complexity of the communication system. ‘A complex system of writing becomes the
possession of a special class and tends to support aristocracies. A simple flexible system of writing admits of
adaptation to the vernacular but slowness of adaptation facilitates monopolies
of knowledge and hierarchies’ (ibid., 4). Thus when a complex system of communication is
replaced by a simpler one, there is deeper penetration into the society. What was formerly reserved for
an elite becomes accessible to a much wider segment of the population.
As a result, there is a
change in the nature of social interaction. Innis described two
periods in history when the number of users of a communications medium
increased dramatically. The first change
came with the invention of the alphabet in the eastern Mediterranean in the
second millennium BC. With the
development of a flexible alphabet, the nature of society changed. ‘A flexible alphabet favoured
the growth of trade, development of trading cities of the Phoenicians and the
emergence of smaller nations dependent on distinct languages’ (ibid., 39). Innis noted the divisive effects of the new technology
within the Roman Empire, which towards its end separated into Greek and Latin
components (ibid., 15).
The second period in which
number became crucial occurred subsequent to the development of printing in
standardized vernacular languages in early-modem Europe. ‘By the end of the sixteenth century the
flexibility of the alphabet and printing had contributed to the growth of
diverse vernacular literatures and had provided a basis for divisive
nationalism in Europe’ (ibid.,
55).
In each case, Innis recognized the nature of the change but was unable to
develop the analytical structure required to treat it theoretically. As a result, number became confused with space
in his analysis. It is only after Innis’s death, with the development of the theory of the
public good by Samuelson (1954) and its application to interest-group
activities by Olson (1965), that
the implications of number became apparent. The larger the number of
contributors to the financing of a public good, the lower the price to each.
To the extent that the institutions
required to support a national written language form a public good, the
taxpayers of each nation will therefore have an interest in increasing the
numbers of its citizens.
Indeed, there is an
additional significance to number. Increasing
number not only lowers the costs but also raises the benefits of information
exchange in the vernacular. When a new
member joins such a system of two-way communications, she confers a benefit - a
network externality - to all existing members of the system, since they can now
communicate with an additional user (Katz and Shapiro
1985). Thus number is a crucial characteristic
of certain media of communication. Here,
then, is a task for those who would write the final movements of Innis’s unfinished symphony: the integration of number into
a model of endogenous change in information technology.
Why should change in
information technology command special attention at the expense of more
traditional areas of interest to economists, such as agricultural techniques,
the development of inanimate power sources, or new means of transport? In a word, communications media are arguably
the most fundamental of ‘enabling technologies’ - techniques that allow us to
use other means of production. [8] Rather than simply providing us with more goods and services
from given inputs, innovations in information processing tend to lead us to
interact differently. Recent research on
primate evolution suggests that greater memory, an increased ability to
communicate over distance, and a fall in the cost of reproducing information
through speech each have had a profound impact on patterns of social organization
(see, e.g., Ghiglieri 1989; Leakey and Lewin 1992; Johanson, Johanson, and Edgar 1994). What is new in the historical period analysed by Innis is that these
changes are external to the individual - the result of cultural rather than
biological evolution.
In November 1952 Harold Innis died of cancer at the age of fifty-eight. His fellow economists, W.T. Easterbrook (1960)
and Mel Watkins (1963), along with Marshall McLuhan
(1962), subsequently paid tribute to him in their writings in the early 1960s. Since then, Innis’s
memory has been kept alive by researchers in other disciplines, who recognize
his contributions to the theory of communications, political science, and
geography. [9] Among economists and economic historians, however, he is
rarely cited. [10] Is there something that economists have missed?
As they have grown older,
many of the most active of later twentieth-century economists have quietly
dropped the assumption of rational, optimizing agents learned in their youth. Friedrich Hayek (1973-9), Kenneth Boulding (1973), Jack Hirshleifer
(1980), Richard Nelson (1987), Douglass North (1990), Nathan Rosenberg (1994),
and Richard Lipsey (1995) are among the more
prominent of those who have become dissatisfied with the limits of neoclassical
economic theory. Seeking both a more
satisfactory way of modelling technological change
and a means of broadening the scope of their analysis to cover cultural
phenomena, they have been attracted by the concept of evolution. All of these researchers appear to have been
preceded by Harold A. Innis, although none has cited Innis’s work on communication in his own writings. The basic concepts of Innis’s
theory of
8. For an analysis of this concept, see Lipsey
and Bekar (1995).
9. For a review of research on Innis’s ideas
on media, see Di Norcia
(1990). Christian (1977) portrays Innis as political
scientist, Parker (1988) as geographer. More recently, Innis’s
writings on media have been cited in the discipline of communications by Geiger
and Newhagen (1993) and Deetz
(1994).
10. Neill (1972) and Parker (1988) are exceptions among economists.
766
social change - bias, balance and the margin - are simply
new terms for the Darwinian concepts of mutation, selection, and reproduction. In addition, Innis
pointed to the importance of communications media as the most fundamental of enabling
technologies.
Yet there is a fundamental
objection to this interpretation of Innis’s later
work as evolutionary economics. At no
point did Innis himself draw a parallel between
Darwin’s concept of evolution as ‘descent with modification’ and his own theory
of social change. Innis’s
posthumously published system of filing cards indicates that he was aware of
Darwin’s impact on nineteenth-century social scientists like Herbert Spencer,
who coined the term ‘survival of the fittest’ (Christian 1980, 7, 39). A possible explanation for his own reticence
to employ Darwinist terminology is that in the late 1940s Darwinism in the
social sciences had received an ugly reputation as a result of racist theories
of natural selection advanced to justify Nazi brutality.
Another interpretation of Innis’s silence on this question is also possible. Innis may have
viewed both Darwin and himself as continuing a much older tradition dating back
to the humanism of the sixteenth century. In his essay, ‘A plea for time,’ the third
chapter of his 1951 book, Innis wrote: ‘The linear
concept of time was made effective as a result of humanistic studies in the
Renaissance... It was not until the Enlightenment that the historical world was
conquered and until Herder and romanticism that the primacy of history over
philosophy and science was established... In the hands of Darwin the historical
approach penetrated biology and provided a new dimension of thought for science
(62-3).
Innis, like
Darwin and Marx, was proposing a historical, path-dependent theory of change. In this sense he was very much a follower of
the German idealist philosopher G.W.F. Hegel, for whom history was a dialectic
process by which conflict between opposing forces is resolved. The title of Innis’s
1947 Quebec address is drawn from the preface to Hegel’s The Philosophy of
Right (1952): ‘When
philosophy paints its grey on grey, then has a shape of life grown old. By philosophy’s grey on grey it cannot be
rejuvenated but only understood. The owl of Minerva spreads its wings only with the falling of the
dusk’ (7). Hegel was saying that
it is only in the final phase of a civilization, when decline is irreversible,
that its culture begins to flower. But
Hegel’s statement, written late in his own life, could also apply to a individual thinker like himself - or Harold Innis. Innis’s great synthesis came late in his life when his hair
was streaked with grey. He died
convinced he had found the means of understanding the nature of his own
civilization. But he himself was by that
time powerless to influence the thinking of his contemporaries.
Today, with the technology
to cram much of world’s learning onto an inexpensive disk available to
children, centralized information storage is becoming obsolete. Our increasing focus on the environment,
social justice, and spiritual values may be explained, at least in part, by our
cheaper access as individuals to the information we need to behave consistently
over time. After seven centuries of what
Harold Innis considered an increasing obsession with
space, the west appears to be moving
in the direction of a more balanced society. The moment perhaps has come for Minerva’s owl
to alight on the shoulders of a new generation.
Binmore, K.
(1992) Fun and Games: A Text on Games Theory (Lexington, MA: Heath)
Boulding,
K.E. (1973) The Economy of Love and Fear (Belmont,
CA: Wadsworth)
Campbell, D.T. (1965)
‘Variation and selective retention in sociocultural
evolution.’ In Social Change in
Developing Areas: A Reinterpretation of Evolutionary Theory, ed. H.R.
Barrington, G.I. Blanksten, and R.W. Mack (Cambridge,
MA.: Schenkman)
Carmichael, H.L. and W.B. MacLeod (1994) ‘Gift giving
and the evolution of cooperation.’
Queen’s University and Université de Montréal Working
Paper
Christian, W. (1977) ‘Harold Innis
as political theorist.’ Canadian
Journal of Political Science 10, 21—42
_________ . (1980) The Idea File of
Harold Adams Innis (Toronto: University of
Toronto Press)
Creighton, D. (1951/1978) Harold Adams Innis:
Portrait of a Scholar (Toronto, University of Toronto Press)
Dawkins, R. (1986) The Blind
Watchmaker (New York: Norton)
Deetz, S.A.
(1994) ‘The micro-politics of identity formation in
the workplace: the case of a knowledge intensive firm.’ Human Studies 17, 23-44
Di Norcia, V. (1990) ‘Communications, time and power: an Innisian view.’ Canadian Journal of Political Science 23,
335-57
Dudley, L. (1991) The Word and the
Sword: How Techniques of Information and Violence Have Shaped Our World (Cambridge,
MA: Basil Blackwell)
Durham, W.H. (1991) Coevolution:
Genes, Culture and Human Diversity (Stanford: Stanford University Press)
Easterbrook, W.T. (1960) ‘Problems in the relationship
of communication and economic history.’ Journal of Economic History 20, 134-5
Freeman, C. (1990) ‘Schumpeter’s Business Cycles revisited.’ In Evolving
Technology and Market Structure: Essays in Schumpeterian Economics, ed. A. Heertje and M. Perlman (Ann
Arbor: University of Michigan Press)
Geiger, S., and J. Newhagen (1993) ‘Revealing the black box: information processing and media
effects.’ Journal of Communication 43, 42-50
Ghiglieri, M.P. (1989) ‘Hominid sociobiology
and hominid social evolution.’ In Understanding
Chimpanzees, ed P.G. Heltne
and L.A. Marquardt (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press)
Campbell, D.T. (1965) ‘Variation and selective
retention in sociocultural evolution.’ In Social
Change in Developing Areas: A Reinterpretation of Evolutionary Theory, ed.
H.R. Barrington, G.I. Blanksten, and R.W. Mack
(Cambridge, MA: Schenkinan)
Hayek, F.A. (1973-9) Law, Legislation and Liberty. 3 vols.
(London: Routledge & Kegan
Paul)
Hegel, G.W.F. (1952) The Philosophy
of Right (Chicago: Encyclopedia Britannica)
Hirschleifer,
J. (1980) ‘Privacy: Its origin, function and future.’ Journal of Legal
Studies 9, 649-64
Innis, H.A.
(1923) A History of the Canadian Pacific Railway (Toronto: McClelland
and Stewart)
_______ . (1930) The Fur Trade in
Canada (Toronto: University of Toronto Press)
_______ . (1940) The Cod Fisheries (Toronto:
University of Toronto Press)
_______ . (1950) Empire and
Communications (Oxford: Clarendon)
_______ . (195 1/1964) The Bias of Communication (Toronto:
University of Toronto Press)
768
Johanson,
D., L. Johanson, and B. Edgar (1994) Ancestors: In
Search of Human Origins (New York: Villard)
Katz, M.L., and C. Shapiro (1985) ‘Network
externalities, competition, and compatiblity.’ American Economic Review 75, 424-40
Leakey, R., and R. Lewin (1992) Origins
Reconsidered: In Search of What Makes Us Human (New York: Doubleday)
Lipsey,
R.G., and C. Bekar (1995) ‘Technical change and
economic growth: continuous random shocks vs. occasional paradigm shifts.’ In Technology,
Information and Public Policy, ed. T.J. Courchene
(Kingston, Os: John Deutsch Institute), forthcoming
Lucas, R.E. Jr (1988) ‘On the mechanisms of
economic development.’ Journal of Monetary Economics 22, 3-42
McLuhan, M.
(1962) The Gutenberg Galaxy: The Making of
Typographic Man (Toronto: University of Toronto Press)
_________ . (1964) ‘Introduction.’ In The
Bias of Communication (Toronto: University of Toronto Press)
Neill, R.F. (1972) A New Theory of Value: The Canadian Economics of
H.A. Innis (Toronto: University of Toronto Press)
Nelson, R.R. (1987) Understanding Technical Change as an Evolutionary
Process (Amsterdam: North-Holland)
North, D.C. (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic
Performance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press)
Olson, M. (1965) The Logic of Collective
Action (Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press)
Paquet, G. (1995) ‘Institutional evolution
in an information age.’ In Technology,
Information and Public Policy, ed. T.J. Courchene
(Kingston, ON: John Deutsch Institute), forthcoming
Parker, I. (1988) ‘Harold Innis
as a Canadian geographer.’ Canadian
Geographer 32, 63-9
Robson, A.J. (1995) ‘The evolution of strategic behaviour.’
This Journal 28, 17-41
Romer, P.M. (1986) ‘Increasing returns and
long-run growth.’ Journal of
Political Economy 94, 1002-37
_________ . (1990) ‘Endogenous technological change.’
Journal of Political Economy 98, S71— S102
Rosenberg, N. (1994) Exploring the Black Box (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press)
Samuelson, P.A. (1954) ‘The pure theory of public
expenditure.’ Review of
Economics and Statistics 36, 387-9
Schumpeter, J.A. (1942) Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy (New
York: Harper)
Watkins, M.H. (1963) ‘A staple theory of economic
growth.’ Canadian Journal of Economics
and Political Science 29, 141-58
Witt, U. (1991) ‘Reflections on the present state of
evolutionary economic theory.’ In Rethinking
Economics, ed. G.M. Hodgson and E. Screpanti (Aldershot, England: Edward Elgar)
769