The Competitiveness of Nations in a Global Knowledge-Based Economy
Paul A. David *
A
Tragedy of the Public Knowledge ‘Commons’?
Global Science,
Intellectual Property and the Digital Technology Boomerang
Electronic Journal of Intellectual Property Rights
Oxford IP Research Centre - Working and Seminar Papers
WP 04/00, 10 September 2000
Content
1. Boomerang - the
Tool and the Metaphor: A Prologue
2. The Digital Dilemma
and the Enterprise of Open Science: An Overview of the Problem
3. The Symbiotic,
Reciprocal Relationships Linking Natural Science Research and ICTs
4. Patronage and
Property in the Production of Knowledge: A Problem of Regime Balance
5. Making Way for the
Market: Legal Rights and the Privatization of Information Goods
6. The European
Commission’s Database Directive and Its Economic Implications
7. What Is To Be
Done? Protecting for Open Science
Research in the Digital Age
This paper draws upon material that was first drafted
as a closing address to the Forum Science, Economie Société Conference “Science et Economie
- les Grands Défis,” held
at the Grand Palais, Paris, on 6-7th May, 1999. Dominique Foray bears some responsibility for
initially encouraging me to work up a version of that speech for wider
circulation. I am grateful to have been
able subsequently to discuss the subject of sui
generis copyright protection of
databases with Wendy Gordon, and David Vaver, and for
the comments received from other participants in the Intellectual Property
Rights Seminar convened by Professor Vaver at St. Petefs College, Oxford (23 November 1999). They improved my still tenuous grasp of many
aspects of U.S. and European copyright law, thereby contributing significantly
to the paper entitled”The Digital Technology
Boomerang” that I presented at the ESF-IIASA-NSF Workshop “Building the Virtual
‘House of Salomon’: Digital Collaboration Technologies, the Organization of
Scientific Work and the Economics of Knowledge Access,” held in Laxenburg, Austria on 3-5 December 1999. On that occasion I benefitted
from the comments made by Bronwyn Hall, Robert Kling, Irving Lerch, Clemente Forero-Pineda, and W. Edward Steinmueller.
Legal scholars still found much in the
revised version (David, 2000) that remained in need of improvement, and I am
indebted especially to Professors Rochelle Dreyfuss
and Jennifer Litman for their discussion of my work
at the Innovation Policy Colloquium meeting, convened ( on
13 April, 2000) in the New York University School of Law’s Engelberg
Center on Innovation Law and Policy. Those
whose help I have the pleasure of acknowledging here are not to be blamed for whatever
errors, omissions and overly contentious opinions have survived in the text.
Radical legal innovations in intellectual property
protection have been introduced by the little noticed European Database
Directive of March 1996. This initiative,
part of the larger institutional transformations initiated in response to the
economic ramifications of rapid progress in digital information technologies,
poses numerous contentious issues in law and economics. These are likely to create ambiguities for
business and non-profit activities in this area for years to come, and the
terms on which those issues are resolved will materially affect the costs and
organizational feasibility of scientific projects that are of global reach and
significance. This is the case
especially in fields such as geology, oceanography and climatology, which
depend heavily upon the collection, management and analysis of large volumes of
observational data that cannot be regenerated. More generally the conduct of open, collaborative
science - along with many of the benefits that flow from it for the developed
and the developing economies alike - may be seriously jeopardized by the
consequences of the new database protections. This raises the spectre
of a new and different “tragedy of the commons,” one created by continuing the
unbalanced pressure to extract greater economic rents by means of controlling
access to information. “(O)ver-fencing,” which is to say, the erection of artificial
cost barriers to the production of reliable public knowledge by means of
reliable public knowledge, threatens the future of “the public knowledge
commons” that historically has proved critically important for rapid advance in
science and technology.
The paper sets out the
economic case for the effectiveness of open, collaborative research, and the
forces behind the recent, countervailing rush to strengthen and expand the
scope of intellectual property rights protection. Focusing upon innovations in copyright law and
the sui generis protection
of hitherto unprotected content, it documents the genesis and analyzes the
economic implications of the EC’s Database Directive, and related legislative
proposals (HR. 3125, HR. 354 and HR. 1858) in the U.S. The discussion concludes by advancing a number
of modest remedial proposals that are intended to promoted greater efforts to arrive
at satisfactory policy solutions for this aspect of “the digital dilemma.”
0
1. Boomerang - the Tool and the Metaphor: A Prologue
When the effects of modern
digital information and communications technologies are considered from the
standpoint of the global communities engaged in scientific research, ICTs can be likened in some respects to a “boomerang.” The boomerang we all know in actuality is a
remarkable creation of Aboriginal Australian ingenuity: a curved wooden tool
devised for hunting. My allusion to it
in the subtitle of this paper, therefore, is wholly metaphorical. The peculiarly interesting property of the
artifact in question lies in its propensity (when properly thrown) to return to
the origin point of its trajectory, should it miss the intended target. This proves quite handy, in permitting the
skilled user armed with only one such projectile to make several attempts in
reasonably close succession to stun small game at a distance. But the same property also means that failure
to pay close attention to the path of the boomerang’s flight is quite likely to
bring the launcher, or those standing close by, a sharp knock on the head.
The boomerang’s aerodynamic
qualities in this regard make it a particularly suitable metaphor for the
larger class of clever human contrivances that harbor the potential to react
back, visiting injury upon those who have launched them. Even the indirect, curving nature of its
return path to the launch point is apposite to the emerging situation that I
wish to discuss on this occasion, as will soon become apparent. This metaphor is meant to fix your attention -
along with that of other leaders from
the worlds of government, industry, academic research and legal authorities
concerned especially with intellectual property rights - upon a number of
seemingly innocuous if not salutary developments in the legal protection of
novel forms of intellectual property that may turn out to be grievously
damaging to the global enterprise of science that holds such enormous
potentials for improving the well-being of people all around the world.
I am refening,
in particular, to the indirect repercussions in the international regime of
copyright protections that have followed in the wake of the recent, spectacular
advance in information technologies. Although indirect, largely unanticipated, and
too little noticed in the midst of the concerns raised over the patenting of
transgenic organisms and genetic material, these legal sequelae
of the digital technology revolution are certainly changing and in some
respects threaten to undermine parts of the institutional infrastructure that
has historically supported the pursuit of reliable and useful knowledge through
open collaboration in scientific research.
The particular problem on
which I want to focus attention here is not simple. Yet, it is possible for me to begin by
presenting its generic features in the following, reasonably simple terms. Knowledge is not an ordinary commodity, but
instead has several properties that economists identify as those characterizing
the general class of “public goods.” As
is well known, competitive markets cannot be relied upon to perform well in
allocating resources to the production and distribution of commodities that
have those properties, because they interfere with the ability of private
investors to fully appropriate the economic benefits that are created by new
knowledge and information goods.
1. The three generally recognized properties are: (1) non-rival possession,
which is made possible by the “perfect expansibility” of ideas; (2) low
marginal cost of reproduction and distribution which makes it more difficult to
exclude others from gaining access to them; (3) substantial fixed costs of
original production. See section 4,
below for further discussion.
1
A variety of market and
non-market institutional mechanisms may be deployed to address the so-called “appropriability problem,” and, typically, several among
these are found to be deployed simultaneously by modem states, in order to
encourage the provision of public goods in the shape of scientific and
technological knowledge. Some years ago,
in another conference presentation to the World Bank, I referred to the three
principal institutional devices as “the three Ps”: public Patronage, state
Procurement (or, alternatively Production), and the legal exclusive ownership
of (intellectual) Property. [2]
But, each of these
exhibit some special deficiencies as well as some specific virtues in its
effects upon resource allocation; none among them offers a perfect solution.
To obtain both rapid
production and distribution of public goods in the form of scientific and
technological knowledge, and to elicit the amount of investment needed in
translating new knowledge into a rapid pace of economic welfare-enhancing
innovation, it therefore is necessary to devise a system in which these
distinct institutionalized mechanisms are kept working properly in conjunction
with one another. In the interests of
improving the long-term performance of the system in generating scientific
advances and technological innovation, no one (among the several means
available for coping with the public goods “appropriability
problem”) should be permitted to encroach upon the spheres in which the others
function most effectively. The design of
each should be re-evaluated and modified where necessary in order to
accommodate, rather than undermine, the viability of complementary
institutional mechanisms.
In other words, the task of
science and technology policy for economic development may be seen to be that
of achieving and maintaining the right balance in the deployment of the several
devices. Recently, however, the opportunities
and disruptive effects created by technological change itself have set in
motion economic and political pressures that are tending to unbalance the
innovation systems of many of the world’s economies. Greater reliance is being placed on the “property”
solution, by extending the domain of private ownership and strengthening the
legal protection of intellectual property rights. The “un-balancing” effect which this is having
within the regime of intellectual property is to be seen in the nature of the
additions made to the ever-widening, and increasingly dubious range of
applications found for established principles of patent, copyright and trade
secrecy law; and also in the creation of quite novel sui
generis legal protections for business investments
involving information-goods, which in some cases have departed radically from
established principles.
But, at the overall
innovation system level, too, imbalances are appearing as a consequence of the
strong and persisting policy consensus that presently favors providing
subsidies for national industrial development in the form of monopoly rights to
the exploitation of new knowledge. The
problem is not so much intellectual property rights mechanism itself, which
although imperfect, has been found to work well enough when it comes to
stimulating private investment in the exploitation of commercial opportunities
based upon existing bodies of scientific and engineering knowledge. [3] What is more problematic for the long run, however, is
that an unchecked bias towards expanding of the
2. See David (1993), esp. pp. 226 ff. The term Patronage stands here for the
institutional arrangements for awarding publicly financed prizes, research
grants based on the submission of competitive proposals for scientific peer
review, and other subsidies to private individuals and organizations engaging
in discovery and invention - in exchange for full public disclosure of their
findings. “Patronage” characterizes the
pursuit of open scientific inquiry and is the dominant institutional and social
mode of organization associated with the conduct of academic research in the
democratic societies of the West. On the
connection between patronage institutions and the historical emergence of open
science, see, e.g., David (1998). Patronage
contrasts most immediately with Procurement, which is associated with
governmental contracting (or direct production) arrangements, generally, and
for performance of scientific research in particular.
3. It is true, of course, that consumers of the innovative goods and
services that are provided under these arrangements will usually bear some
burden in the form of the higher prices that monopoly-holders may extract so
long as they enjoy their temporary freedom from the competition of imitators. But this already is widely acknowledged, and
so does not require the same attention as the issue upon which this paper is
focused.
domain of information-goods within which private property
institutions and market mechanisms flourish, is steadily encroaching upon the
domain of public information. In doing
so, it has tended to weaken, and may in the end seriously undermine those
non-market institutions which historically have proved themselves to be
especially effective in sustaining rapid growth in the scientific and
technological knowledge base that is available to be exploited.
So much for this
introductory, capsule sketch of the generic and necessarily rather abstract
features of the increasingly worrisome situation that has emerged in the past
decade, and which adversely affects the prospects for future knowledge-driven
economic development. Now I must try to
indicate in considerably more specific terms one particular set of issues that
connect the future vitality of the global communities engaged in open science
research, and the present trajectory of the evolving legal protections accorded
to intellectual property rights in science and technology. In addition to being an especially fraught
manifestation of the larger problem, the ways in which these two areas of concern
are linked with each other, and entangled with the effects of the revolution
that has taken place in digital communications technologies, in themselves make
for an illuminating story. The case of
the “digital technology boomerang” offers yet another illustrative
exemplification of the importance of adopting a systems-analysis approach when
setting policies for science, technology and economic development.
The current acceleration of
the process of modifying statutory provisions for the protection of copyrights
to better adapt them to the realities of the new technological milieu, has been
set in motion by the astounding scientific and engineering achievements in
digital computation and telecommunications. But, it should be recalled that publicly
funded research groups in the international basic science communities
historically have played pioneering roles in launching the digital revolution. [4] What strikes me as being particularly ironic, as well as
disturbing in the present situation, is that the likely effects of the
reactions that have been triggered in the intellectual property rights regime
are of a kind so inimical to the health of other, long-standing practices and
institutional arrangements for the exchange of information and data. Not accidentally, the latter arrangements are
critically important for the continuing advancement of scientific knowledge. Consequently, the digital revolution’s
unexpected legal side effects may vitiate the direct economic benefits that
enhanced information and communications technology (ICT) otherwise might have
been expected to provide to the international research community. Will the mode of scientific inquiry that was
responsible in great measure for the technological foundations of the modern
information revolution thus receive a collective “knock on the head” - through
the agency of their own technical creations? Yes, quite possibly, especially if we are
inattentive to the path along which the digital technology boomerang appears to
be moving.
Innovations that create
unexpected disruptive and destructive effects of a reflexive kind, damaging to
the economic, social and cultural environs of their creators, although not
directly injurious to those who initiated them, certainly have figured
frequently in the historical annals of science and technology. Of course a more vivid rendition of that
general theme continues to flourish in literary and popular imagination,
following its classic expression in Mary Shelley’s tale of the inventor Frankenstein.
If one doubts
that this vision of the dangers of scientific hubris remains very much with us
today, consider that at the height of the recent European hysteria over the
testing and marketing of genetically modified plants, the favorite headline of
Britain’s tabloid press was: “FRANKENSTEIN FOODS!”
What I have in mind,
however, bears scant resemblance to that hackneyed allegory of the unwitting
scientist unleashing an uncontrollable monster. Rather, the tenor of the discussion I aim to
stimulate by my reference to “the digital technology boomerang” is much more akin
to the one initiated by Rachel Carson’s Silent Spring in 1962. The publication of that book called attention
to the indirect and complex pathways through which the products of human
chemical ingenuity (then being liberally applied in eradicating insect-borne
disease
4. See, e.g., National Research Council (1999) for one recently
documented part of this history.
3
and enhancing agricultural productivity) were poisoning
the human habitat. At the very least,
the ironic theme of impending reflexive injury may prove useful in the present
context, if it serves only to raise the awareness of members of the world’s
research communities of the threatening changes that are now taking place in
their institutional environment. The
particular problem I have chosen to examine on this occasion will be seen to
deviate from the canonical literary form in at least one respect: this is not
going to be a story in which the authors of some scientific or technological
breakthrough are able to walk away comparatively unscathed from the disruption
and damage that the practical fruits of their research unexpectedly have
visited upon the rest of society.
2. The Digital Dilemma and the Enterprise of Open Science:
An Overview of the Problem
The explosive developments
that currently transform computer-mediated electronic communications most
certainly will impinge in various ways upon the organization and conduct of
scientific and engineering research. The
emergence of new communications facilities that are available at dramatically
reduced costs affects everything from new, electronic working paper and journal
publications, and specialized dynamic database services, to the prospective
growth of an upgraded Internet that will support enhanced information search,
filtering and retrieval services, virtual laboratory environments, and remote
shared access to large experimental research facilities. These tools are almost certain to alter
profoundly the way that normal science research projects are organized and
funded during the 21 century. But, if
the opportunities of collaboration and sharing of both physical and data
resources on a global scale are in the process of being greatly expanded, there
also are counter-tendencies that may undermine long-established traditions of
co-operation and curtail the domain of open scientific endeavor.
It is upon this second,
more troubling aspect that I wish to focus, namely, the implications for the
enterprise of open science of the nexus that has formed between the digital
technology revolution and the process of institutional innovation that is
transforming the regime of intellectual property rights in science and
technology. [5] The swing of
the policy pendulum in the U.S. and other highly advanced economies towards
more extensive reliance upon strengthened patent and copyright protection for
innovations, part of which has been the portrayal of these legal provisions as
crucial for eliciting private investment in invention and commercialization of
new products, has received impetus from a number of distinct sources. In some measure it was a defensive reaction to
the emergence during the 1980’s of intensified global competition from new
producers who had acquired surprising technical capabilities, especially in
rapidly absorbing new production methods and applying these to imitate, adapt
and eventually elaborate upon novel goods first introduced in the advanced
economies.
Secondly, some added
momentum was gained from undertakings on the part of fiscally straightened governments
during the 1990’s to cut expenditures by transferring to the private sector a
range of data production and information distribution activities that formerly
were publicly provided. A third factor
has been the rise of venture financing for new technology-based start-up
companies, and the role that the existence of a portfolio of patents came to
play, as both a signal of creative scientific and engineering competence, and a
useful impediment to the rapid entry of competition into the market niche targeted
by the new enterprise. The same may be
said in regard to some forms of copyright, although the legal protections they
afford generally are thought to be weaker and potentially less valuable than
those which patents can provide. But not
only venture capitalists and business managers are attracted by the commercial
advantages that may be secured by obtaining intellectual property rights; the
more entrepreneurially inclined scientists and engineers among those engaged in
university-based and public foundation sponsored research, increasingly are
found
5. On the nature and historical origins of “open science,” see, e.g., Dasgupta and David (1987, 1994); David (1998).
seeking patents or copyrights for their discoveries and
inventions. Indeed, recent changes in
government policy affecting the technology licensing of activities of
universities and public institutes have been encouraging this new trend.
Fourthly, behind much of
the impetus to adapt inherited regimes of copyright protection for use in the
new technological environment of digital coding and electronic data
transmission and copying, one can discern strong economic interests seeking to
contain the disruptive effects upon traditional business models in the
publishing industries, as well as to facilitate the commercial exploitation of
these new digital technologies.
Fifthly, and surely most
significantly in recent years, in fields such as biomedicine, information
technologies and telecommunication network services the rapid pace of advance
of discovery and invention has heightened the drive on the part of business
concerns to find more effective mechanisms of protection against the
profit-destroying entry of “copy-cat competitors.” This reflects the fact that innovative commodities
in those fields tend to be characterized by the combination of high fixed costs
of development with very low unit costs of reproduction, rendering the position
of the lead innovator especially perilous if others can simply copy and
replicate their products.
Statutory modifications of
the intellectual property regime are thus seen by many as essential if the new
technical capabilities for electronic network distribution of digitized
information are not to be crippled by an obsolescent institutional infrastructure,
such as the protection of copyright that has evolved from the grants of
monopoly privileges made to printers in the era of Guttenberg. [6] It is both evident and understandable that IPR
innovations generally are being directed towards facilitating the continued
workings of markets in the age of electronic publishing and distribution of
entertainment products (music and video); and towards providing incentives for
more private investment in developing convenient means for consumers to access
the contents of digital message streams.
It is evident that in
publishing industries experimentation with new business models has been induced
by the new, digital technology-based created economic conditions of negligible
transmission and copying costs. Typical
of the transformed business strategies has been the provision of nominally
priced or freely distributed data and applications programs, coupled with the
offer of related (upgraded, enhanced and more up-to-date) information goods and
services on a fee-for-service basis. New
computer-based methods of encryption, and copy-protection, along with digital
monitoring techniques (e.g., embedded “watermarks”) that can be deployed by the
distributor to thwart unauthorized reproduction of digitized material, have
also are being deployed; in some instances to reinforce old business models
based upon copyright protection, but cases as a means of implementing a
two-part pricing strategy for marketing information goods that does not depend
upon the protections of copyright laws.
The phrase “the digital
dilemma’” lately has begun to be applied in referring to the challenge posed by
the need not only to accomplish the supply-side tasks of adapting the business
of publishing to the digital age, but also to do so without seriously
sacrificing the economic interests of the ultimate users of data and
information. The newly augmented, fully
digital information infrastructure - comprising computer networks, the
integrated set of technologies that constitute the World Wide Web, and the distributed
libraries of information in digital form - is at once a remarkably powerful
medium for publishing, distributing and controlling information, and the
world’s largest reproduction facility. It has the potential to enormously improve
access to information, and, at the same time it affords technological means of
inhibiting access in ways that were never before practical.
6. On the historical evolution of copyright protections, see, e.g.,
David (1994) and references therein.
7. See National Research Council (2000), esp. pp. 1-3.
5
In discussions about how a
proper balance between those effects might be managed through changes in
intellectual property institutions, it is well recognized that it may not be
possible to steer a course that avoids winding up with one or the other of the
classic policy mistakes. On the one
side, there is the risk of not leaving sufficient profit incentives for
commercial producers of novel information goods and services, whereas on the
other side, there is the danger that society as a whole will have been burdened
to an unnecessary degree by the inefficiencies in resource allocation that
result from the legally sanctioned restraints placed on access to existing
bodies of knowledge and information-goods. In addition, of course, there is the vexed
question of how the benefits of the induced innovations are to be shared: is
the societal need for more investment of the sort that will be forthcoming
sufficiently great to justify giving intellectual property owners (particularly
copyright-holders) the unrestricted power to charge whatever prices they wish? Should they thus be allowed to shift in their
favor the distribution of whatever incremental producer and consumer surpluses
have been created commercializing the innovation?
The essential nature of the
“trade-offs” between opposing economic interests that currently animates these
questions is not new. Indeed, it has
been aired thoroughly in the long history of policy debates over the benefits
and costs of creating temporary intellectual property monopolies in order to
encourage investment in commercially-oriented innovation activities. Yet, those national and international debates
have been much preoccupied with patent issues; and even in the past and recent
discussions of “the digital dilemma,” relatively little attention has been
devoted to the ways in which the protection of intellectual property rights in
the digital age may obstruct shared access to reliable and up-to-date
information and data, and thereby seriously impede the systematic accumulation
of scientific knowledge. As a
consequence of the construction of novel and potentially legal rights in
intellectual property, and the encouragement of public and quasi-public
institutions in making use of these to attract private sector funding as a way
of meeting the high first-costs of making digitized archives available on electronic
networks, larger and larger portions of the public data “commons” are being
“enclosed” and transformed into private monopolies.
This unintended consequence
of the digital technology revolution actually may sap the future vitality of
the global public science system. That
possibility has been rendered worrisomely plausible by the direct implications
and some unanticipated sequelae of the
European Commission’s Directive on the Legal Protection of Databases, which was
issued in 1996. Even today, not many
among those who should be concerned actually are aware of the provisions that
it requires the EU member countries to implement in their national statutes. The Directive in effect established a new form
of copyright in databases, one that extends to contents previously in the
public domain and otherwise not copyrightable. It narrowly restricted the application of the
principle of allowing exclusions for “fair use” in research, and it permitted
virtually indefinite renewal of copyright protection for databases without
requiring the substantial addition of new and original content.
In addition to initiating
mimetic legislative proposals in the U.S. Congress, the radical innovations
introduced by the European Database Directive has posed a number of contentious
issues in law and economics which are likely to create ambiguities for business
and non-profit activities in this area for years to come. The ways in which these are resolved will
materially affect the costs and organizational feasibility of carrying through
some kinds of scientific projects that are of global reach and significance,
especially those in the fields of geology, oceanography and climatology that
depend heavily upon the collection, management and analysis of very large volumes
of observational data.
Thus, the spectre before us is that of a new and different “tragedy
of the commons.” It would be the tragic
destruction of the public knowledge base necessary for scientific and
technological research by “over-fencing” - the erection of artificial barriers
whose purpose is the extraction of economic rents. [8] Unless systematic monitoring of such incursions can be
8. The “tragedy of the anticommons” is a
phrase coined by I-Teller and Eisenberg (1998) to refer to the problem of
excessive fragmentation of patent rights in the technological knowledge base
for commercially-oriented [innovation
activities, which may inhibit private investment by imposing heavy transactions
costs in assembling the necessary licensing rights. Use of this label is eschewed because the
focus of concern here is on a different problem, involving obstacles to
academic researchers’ rapid access to informational inputs required for their
work.]
HHC: [bracketed] displayed on page 7 of original.
organized on a g1obal scale, and unless countervailing
measures, such as compulsory licensing provisions, can be mounted quickly both
at the national and international levels, the conduct of open, collaborative
science - along with many of the benefits that flow from it, for the developed
and the developing economies alike - may be seriously jeopardized. Ironically, and surely it would be a wicked
and avoidable historical irony, serious damage could be done to the
institutions and norms of open by these unintended repercussions of the very
same digital technologies to whose development public sector science itself
contributed so crucially, and from which it otherwise might derive so much
reinforcement.
The following sections of
this paper undertake more fully to describe and document the developments to
which I have been pointing. They
indicate the importance for future economic growth and human well-being of
checking and where possible reversing the rush towards stronger and more
comprehensive intellectual property protections; and especially preventing that
movement from further unbalancing national and trans-national systems of
science-based innovation. They examine
more closely the complex of historical circumstances that have given rise to
the present mixture of opportunity and danger that posed the “digital dilemma”
facing policy-makers today. They analyze
the genesis and implications of the EC’s Directive on database protection, as
an illustrative exemplification of what has gone wrong, and could continue to
go wrong. The paper concludes by asking
“What can be done?” and makes a number of modest remedial proposals, by way of
encouraging greater efforts to arrive at satisfactory policy answers.
3. The Symbiotic, Reciprocal Relationships Linking
Natural Science Research and ICTs
To fully savor the irony of
the “digital boomerang”, one must start with an appreciation of the basic
research communities’ long history of contributing new materials, tools and
methods to the world of commercial production and distribution. Of course, technological advances in the
industrial production of equipment and instruments, as well as in materials
such as chemical reagents, reciprocally have been augmenting the power of
experimental and observations research methods and re-directing the aims of
scientific inquiry at an ever-accelerating pace since the seventeenth century. Few facets of this reciprocal relationship
have had more profound impact than the evolving nexus between scientific
research and information and communication technologies (ICT5). Beginning with systematic inquiry into
semiconductor effects, leading to the invention of the transistor at Bell
Laboratories in the 1950’s, and continuing with developments in the field of
solid state physics, lasers and fibre optics,
injections of new scientific knowledge have provided a basis for the continuing
accumulation of innovations and improvements in computers and computer-mediated
telecommunications.
In addition, research
programs in the fundamental and applied natural sciences have historically been
important drivers of ICT advance, due to the performance requirements and
novelty of scientific instrumentation and the heavy computational demands in
some fields of scientific investigation, such as nuclear and high energy particle
physics; and, more recently, in geophysics and the observational environmental
sciences. Thus, “pressures” for
improvements in data processing, and information storage, transmission and
retrieval capabilities, which were generated on the research frontier in
decades past, have induced significant information technology innovations whose
spreading application has begun to have major societal and economic
consequences. It was the needs of the
geographically dispersed university-based researchers engaged in the Advanced
Research Program to enable digital information exchanges across heterogeneous
computer platforms that issued in the design of the simple, robust (TPCIIP)
data communication protocols that were used first in
7
the ARPAnet, then in NSFnet, and eventually made possible the explosive
extension of the Internet. Similarly
well known are the proximate basic science contexts that fostered the creation
of the World Wide Web browser technology, from the efforts of Timothy Berners-Lee
to provide a digital information linkage system that would support the needs of
the global community of particle physicists working on the experimental
facilities constructed at CERN. [9]
Information and
communication technology, in turn, has been reshaping the conduct of scientific
activities and significantly augmenting the task productivity of research
workers in many fields. [10] It has done so by providing, in the shape of the computer, an ever more
powerful general purpose scientific instrument - available for simulation, the
generation of experimental variety and optimization in more realistic models of
real world systems, as well as for controlling, recording and analyzing
experimental and observational data. The
use of ICTs for facilitating scientific exchange
includes the formation of linkages between research communities and among
individual researchers on a global basis.
Data communication methods are increasingly valuable in providing access
to experimental data, much of which is extraordinarily expensive to gather
(e.g. space missions) or represent a unique resource for the study of dynamic
systems (e.g. satellite and oceanic observation). In recent years, the potential of data communication
has been extended beyond the aerospace and oceanic applications to the remote
control or remote management of scientific instruments for experimental
investigation, involving some of the most complex trials of “tel-working” (involving real time distant collaboration)
that have been undertaken.
The growing use of ICTs in scientific investigation is producing a rapid accumulation
of stocks of observational data, mathematical models of real world systems,
simulation and other data generated from computation, descriptive and
explanatory information about scientific subjects, and so forth. For convenience all of these types of data and
information can be referred to as “scientific data” or “information.” The accumulation of this scientific
information in ways that facilitate its use by and distribution to other
researchers is an important, nay, a crucial means of realizing the
potentialities for closer co-ordination and integration of research, and to
support further specialization and augmentation of capabilities within the international
science community.
It is not yet clear whether
the great advances in computer mediated communications have been the driving
force behind the rising frequency of international scientific collaboration
that has become more pronounced since the late 1980’s, or whether these simply
facilitated a trend impelled by other developments, including the ending of the
Cold War. [12] But it is evident that open and easy exchanges of
published information and underlying data among the participating researchers
remain essential to the success of this particular form of remote co-operative
work, as well as for rapid dissemination and evaluation of research findings. Increasingly, research in the sciences
(including the social sciences) has come to be organized through networks, and conducted
by teams whose members are drawn from geographically separated institutions and
research units. They
9. See, for recent accessible accounts of the Internet’s history, e.g., Abbate (1999) and Naughton
(1999); on the development of the World Wide Web, Berners-Lee (1999), CERN
(1997).
10. See, Moulton, Young and Eberhardt (1990)
for an early and unusually revealing attempt at quantitative assessment.
11. While some authoritative discussions of issues affecting the exchange
of scientific data (e.g., National Research Council 1997) have been limited to
considering access only to data generated and used in the “natural sciences,”
the same questions arise in the social sciences.
12. Worldwide, the proportion of publications in (selected) scientific
journals covering mathematics, physics, chemistry and biology that had
international collaborators increased from 6 percent to 8 percent between 1981 and
1986, jumped to 11 percent by 1991 and reached 15 percent in 1995. See European Commission (1999), p 40: Table 2;
Walsh and Bayrna (1996).
utilize data from multiple sources, varying in
character and size from the results of a single observational experiment
presented in a table of a journal article, to the enormous collections of
observations compiled from the readout of meteorological remote-sensing instruments,
geographic information systems, particle accelerators, and the systematic
aggregations of research findings that form specialized databases of chemical,
genomic, medical, or epidemiological information. Such data sets may in turn be recombined and
merged with new material to create new databases, the analysis of whose
contents may yield novel scientific findings.
Thus, for open science
research communities, databases are dynamic tools, not merely static
sources to be passively consulted; they are formed and kept effective through
an interactive process of examination, error-correction, updating, and
incremental elaboration that engages the critical expertise of many individuals
in the communities of researchers who co-operate in developing, certifying and
maintaining these research instruments. Thus,
in many contexts the value of the information to users is enhanced by the very
fact that its use has been, and will continue to be shared with other
researchers. Of course, that does not
imply that information in the form of scientific databases must be made freely
available to individual researchers and teams; government research grants, and
the budgets of academic institutions today commit significant sums for the
purchase of commercially produced databases. But, what it may mean is that the quality of
specialized database services provided, and the commitment to the maintenance
of the resource’s availability that is likely to be required and expected by a
community of expert researchers, cannot profitably be guaranteed by commercial
database producers. Furthermore, whether
scientific databases are produced by business firms or by co-operating
researchers, it is important that the conditions imposed upon the users remain
sufficiently convenient and flexible to support the open and rapid exchange of
information: the effectiveness of these research instruments needs to be
protected from being impaired by proprietary protection schemes that render
use, reuse and recombination of the contents technically awkward and
economically burdensome.
Despite the enormous
potential of ICTs for facilitating and enhancing
collaborative scientific investigations, one must recognize the enormous differences
in the actual use made of these technologies that presently exists among the
variety of research disciplines and national scientific communities. The disparities that persist in the
availability and employment of ICTs among the world’s
scientists and engineers are not unlike the pronounced inequality we observe in
the general material conditions under which researchers, along with other
members of the globe’s population live and work; and, indeed, some among those
disparities arise from inter-connected causes. The broad geographical distribution of modern scientific
and technological research across the globe is strongly congruent with the
spatial pattern of high-productivity economic activities and high level of
wealth per person. At the beginning of
the 1990’s over four-fifths of all qualified scientists and engineers (some
four million plus, in nember) were to be found in the
“industrial” countries (including Australia, New Zealand and South Korea within
that category); and fully two-thirds of the total were concentrated in North
America, Western Europe, Eastern Europe and the western republics of the USSR. India and China together held approximately
another 15 percent of the total, leaving only about 5 percent of the world’s
scientific and engineering workforce distributed among all the rest of
“developing” (and “non-developing”) economies. [13] The distribution of R&D expenditures, of course, is
even more strongly skewed in favor of the advanced, industrial nations.
A survey by Annerstedt (1994), based on a variety of quantitative and
qualitative indicators of institutionalized scientific research capabilities
among the LDCs found 55 countries, mostly the African
nations, still lacking any significant “indigenous science and technology base”
at the beginning of the 1990’s. The
essential elements of a domestic science and technology base were judged to be
present in another group, comprising 40 or so
13. See Annerstedt (1994), Table 3; and pp.
115ff, for the following discussion of the varied capabilities for
participation in international scientific research found among the LDCs.
9
countries (Algeria, Ghana, Indonesia, Iraq, Malaysia, Paraguay
and Sri Lanka, among them). But, even
though countries in this category were found to have a potential to activate a
higher proportion of qualified personnel in commercially oriented R&D, the
absolute numbers of scientists and engineers effectively engaged with
agricultural and industrial production enterprises were still very low. Thus, only about 40 among the 130 or so LDC’s covered by the survey were deemed to possess a
“solid” indigenous science and technology base, providing a potential for
endogenous technological innovation and the ability to sustain some significant
degree of collaboration in international scientific projects.
Effective contribution to
the work of the global science communities by researchers situated in this
latter group of (truly) “developing” economies (which includes the Asian NICs, and some Latin American countries, such as Argentina,
Brazil, Mexico and Venezuela) is not guaranteed, however. It remains crucially dependent upon their
having access to libraries of international working papers and archival
publications, current databases, as well as to high-speed telecommunication links
with distant collaborators and expensive external research facilities. Timely access of this kind is far from
ubiquitously available, and lacking the means to assure such “connectivity,”
even the most highly trained researchers experience marginalization, rapid
obsolescence of their expertise, and frustration in their chosen lines of
scientific investigation, upon returning to their native countries - as many
nevertheless continue to do for reasons both personal and patnotic.
[14]
Of course, there are issues
here of equity, and of the entitlement of people from many societies and
cultures to participate in advancing knowledge - especially when that is not
only likely to transform the human condition generally, but may specifically
impinge upon their lives and those of their children. But, quite apart from these matters, one
should recognize that the highly unequal material endowments of the world’s
research scientists would affect the future conduct of research on questions of
global concern. Many of the scientific
challenges of the coming century concern our understanding of the global environment
and eco-systems. The disparities between
the rich and poor regions of the world in their scientific resources and
capabilities for participation in global research networks hinder our
collective ability to gather, integrate and analyze observational data from numerous,
spatially distributed locations. Ease of
access to shared network resources, including digital archives, dictionaries,
and dynamic databases, as well as to the use of observational and computational
facilities, is an essential part of the infrastructure enabling such
transnational collaborative programs of research. The technical conditions for providing such
access at greatly reduced costs have been created, and will continue to
improve, but other, less propitious developments may turn out to vitiate the
benefits that such achievements seemed to promise the world’s open science
research communities.
4. Patronage and Property in the Production of
Knowledge: A Problem of Regime Balance
The impending “tragedy of
the public knowledge commons,” which seems to be a predictable outcome of the
unopposed forces that are driving expansion of the domain IPR and privatization
of knowledge, differs diametrically from the form of “tragedy” famously
recounted in the well-known work by Garett Hardin
(1968). The latter was a highly
evocative essay that is still cited frequently in support of the view that
un-priced natural resources will be destroyed by unregulated access and
exploitation. The difference lies in the
character of the resources. The ideas
and data that form the public information commons are not like pasturelands
that may be reduced to unproductive desert by over-grazing, or schools of fish
that may be harvested to the point of extinction. Knowledge and information may be
14. See, e.g., Gaillard (1994) for an
interesting although pessimistic appraisal of their situation, based in good
part upon analysis of survey responses from 489 LDC-resident scientist
researchers, mostly in the agricultural and biological sciences, who between
1974 and 1984 had received grants from the International Foundation for Science
(a non-governmental multilaterally funded organlization
that provides support to young scientists in and from developing countries).
concurrently utilized by many without diminishing their
availability to any of the users, and they will not become “depleted” through
intensive use.
This hardly is a modem
insight, for the point was made almost two hundred years ago with precision and
elegance in a letter penned to a Baltimore inventor by Thomas Jefferson in
1813: “He who receives an idea from me, receives instruction himself without
lessening mine; as he who lights his taper at mine, receives light without
darkening me.” For Jefferson, this was a
consequence of nature having “peculiarly and benevolently” arranged that “ideas
should freely spread from one to another over the globe, for the moral and
mutual instruction of man... when she designed them, like fire, expansible over
all space, without lessening their density at any point, and like the air in
which we breathe, move, and have our physical being, incapable of confinement
or exclusive appropriation.” [15]
Modem economics identifies
this property of information (infinite expansibility) as one of the two
characteristics defining that special category of commodities known as “pure
public goods,” the other being the costliness of excluding others from
possession of an idea once it has been disclosed. More is at stake in the present context than a
definition: the economic significance of the public goods nature of ideas and
data is that the operation of competitive markets cannot be relied upon to
yield price signals that lead to socially efficient outcomes with respect to
the production and distribution of such commodities. From this condition flows the logic of public
patronage for fundamental, exploratory research, the outcomes of which
constitute vital informational “inputs” that guide and enhance the expected
rate of economic returns from investment in commercial applications-oriented
R&D. Adhering to the analytical
economics perspective that what is being protected by patents and copyrights is
the exclusive right to the commercial exploitation of information, proves
especially useful when one comes to consider the implications for scientific
research activities of statutory obstacles to information access that have been
created, and may yet be given force by the movement to strengthen and extend
protection for intellectual property.
There is much to be said
from the viewpoint of both legal theory and economic analysis for interpreting
patent and copyright institutions as remarkably ingenious social contrivances,
whereby protection of the discoverer’s or inventor’s exclusive right to
commercially exploit new knowledge is exchanged for the disclosure of
information that creates a public good; and, moreover, a public good that may
be drawn upon to produce additional discoveries and inventions. [16] Nevertheless, it ought not to be supposed that the actual
provisions of the laws affecting intellectual property rights fully honor this
social bargain. True, no patent is valid
that does not describe the invention in “clear, precise, and exact terms,”
thereby disclosing sufficient information to enable second-comers to practice
the invention without “undue experimentation.” American patent law is unusual in going
farther than this, in requiring the patent applicants to disclose the best mode
in which they contemplate implementing their invention. But, in practice these provisions often prove
insufficient to overcome the effects of the economic incentives that patentees
usually have to withhold some pertinent information, either for their private
use or as a basis to extract additional rents for the transfer of know-how that
is complementary to that disclosed by the patent.
Delays in the release of
information add to the academic research community’s concerns over the way that
the workings of the patent system restrict access to new scientific and
technological findings. U.S. patent law
follows the principle that priority in invention, rather than being first to
file a patent application is what matters; it therefore allows applicants a
one-year grace period after publication. But most foreign systems award patents
15. David (1993) may be consulted for references, and further
discussions of these passages in Jefferson’s writings.
16. For the legal and economic interpretations, respectively, see, e.g.,
Eisenberg (1989), and Dasgupta and David (1987,
1994), David (1994).
11
on a “first to file” basis, which means that even
American researchers are induced - by their own or their supporting
organization’s commercial goals - to delay publication of their findings and
inventions until they have prepared patent applications to secure rights in
other countries. During the two decades
following the passage of the 1980 Bayh-Dole Act,
which authorized universities in the U.S. to seek patents on innovations
arising from federally funded research projects, there has been more-or-less
continuous modification of institutional rules in the direction of lengthening
the permissible duration of delays placed on the publication of research
findings for purposes of allowing the filing of patent applications. [17]
From the standpoint of
academic researchers the greatest deficiency of the statutory disclosure
requirements imposed by patent laws is simply that little scientific or technical
data may be divulged in meeting this stipulation, so that the patent itself is
of only limited interest and serves mainly as a notice that the patentees may
be willing to supply more useful information, for some fee. Moreover, researchers’ ability to make use of
such information as the patent does divulge is by no means assured until the
end of its life; the patent not only excludes others from selling the
invention, but also prohibits them from making and using it. That the use of an invention for purposes of
research, and hence in generating further discoveries and innovations, ought
not be proscribed has long been recognized by patent case law in the US:
researchers have been allowed to defend themselves from infringement suits on
grounds of “experimental use” - so long as the infringer is able to show that
no commercial benefit was derived thereby. [18]
The same situation does not
arise with conventional copyright protection, since what is being protected is
the published form in which ideas have been expressed; only that which is fully
disclosed can qualify the author for legal protection against infringers. Inasmuch as it is difficult, if not impossible
to establish that unauthorized copies were made of a text which had not been
made public in some way, authors seeking legal protection for their work have
every incentive to hasten its disclosure. Moreover, in recognition of the cultural and
scientific benefits of exegetical and critical writings, and further research based
upon published information and data - not to mention the interests of authors
in having such usage made on the basis of accurate representations of their
work - statutory exceptions traditionally are provided to permit “fair use”
infringements of copyrighted material. Largely for these reasons, this form of
intellectual property protection historically has not raised serious objections
on the grounds of impeding rapid access to new scientific or technological data
and information.
But, more recently, the
extension of copyright to software has permitted a breach of the disclosure
principle that parallels the one already noted in regard to patents: under
American copyright law (in order to qualify to pursue infringers for damages)
it is sufficient to register only some sample extracts of a computer program’s
“text,” rather than the entire body of code. Moreover, there is no requirement whatsoever
to disclose the underlying “source code”; copyright protection can be obtained
on the basis of a disclosure of just the machine language instructions, which,
even were they to be divulged in their entirety would
17. The effects of the Bayh-Dole legislation
(U.S .C. § §200-211: 291-307) on university patenting activity are reviewed by
Mowery and Nelson (1998); Cohen, Florida and Goe
(1996) report findings from a survey of U.S. university-industry research
centers on the distribution of permitted restraints on publication to allow for
the filing of patent applications, and the significance of these delays and
other restrictions is discussed by David (1995).
18. Dam (1999: pp. 7-8) points out that because the case law has tended
to reject the “experimental use” defense against infringement suits whenever
the researcher might profit, this exception to patent protection is less likely
to prove beneficial for academic researchers in fields like biomedical
sciences, where even publicly-funded “basic” research may yield short-term
economic payoffs. Given the case law
precedents in the U.S., the drive on the part of university administrators to
exploit patent rights under the provisions of the 1980 Bahy-Dole
Act may thus be seen as contributing indirectly as well as directly to creating
more formidable barriers to the ability of academic researchers to rapidly
access new research tools and results.
be difficult and costly to interpret and re-utilize
without access to the source code. While
this practice surely can be seen to violate the principle that no burden of
“undue experimentation” should be placed upon second comers, the latter
requirement is one that holds only in the case of patent law. It never was contemplated that one might be
able to register a text for full copyright protection without practically
disclosing its contents to interested readers.
A further, more generally
disconcerting set of developments may prove quite destructive to the
effectiveness of traditional safeguards against “fair use” exemptions for
research (and educational) purposes - even where such provisions continue to be
made. This threat has emerged only
recently in the form of digital technologies that limit “on line” copying of
electronic information. Advanced
encryption systems now underpin many computing and communications security
services, and permit a wide variety of security objectives to be achieved by
establishing discretionary control over access to encrypted data, along with
assurance for both users and service provider of message authentication and
data integrity, as well as privacy and confidentiality goals. There are other techniques for marking and
monitoring the use of distributed digital information, such as “water marking,”
which attaches a signal to digital data that can be detected or extracted later
to make documentable assertions about its provenance,
authenticity, or ownership; “fingerprinting” embeds a mark in each copy that
uniquely identifies the authorized recipient. “Self help” or “copyright management” systems
that make use of encryption or prevent unauthorized copying of “cleartext” allow copyright holders to enforce their legal
claim to capture economic value from users of the protected material, and,
moreover enable selective access to elements of content that makes it more
feasible for the vendor to engage in price discrimination. Marking and monitoring techniques, in
contrast, do not allow direct enforcement of copyrights, but can be used to
deter unauthorized copying and distribution of information by facilitating
tracking of errant data to the original recipients who were responsible for its
improper use.
These advances in digital
technology have a direct economic effect that is efficiency enhancing, insofar
as they reduce the costs of enforcing a statutory property right and thereby
securing whatever societal benefits copyright legislation is designed to
promote. Yet, in the currently
prevailing enthusiasm for stronger intellectual property protection, the
American drafters of the 1998 Digital Millennium Copyright Act included a
provision that prohibits the circumvention of “any technological measure that
effectively controls access” to a copyrighted work, and outlawed the
manufacture, importation or public distribution of any technology primarily
produced for the purpose of such circumvention. [19]
The
problem posed by this statutory reinforcement for applications of novel
self-help technologies is simply that it may render impossible the exercise
“fair use” of copyrighted material by researchers and educators, leaving the
provision of information access for such purposes as a matter for the
discretion of copyright holders.
This, however, is not the
only serious assault upon the traditional means of permitting publicly
supported open science communities to pursue their work untrammeled by the protections
afforded to copyright owners. As
attractive as the prospect of more powerful “self help” technologies may appear
to be in curtailing “digital piracy,” such remedies would create a threat to
the achievement of a reasonably regime for the allocation of scientific and
technological information goods while providing protection for private
investments in information goods. One
way in which it is feasible to approximate the efficient workings of a system
of discriminatory pricing for data and information is to allow educators,
scholars and researchers to invoke “fair use” exemptions from the requirements
for licensing material that is copyrighted or otherwise legally protected by
statute. In effect, this approach would
set differentially lower prices for the use of information goods in producing
and distributing knowledge - indeed, prices that approximate the negligibly
small marginal costs of digital reproduction and transmission.
19. See Digital Millennium Copyright Act (1998), United States Code, 17,
§1201; also, Dam (1998) for discussion of the policy issues raised
by self-help systems.
13
5. Making Way for the Market: Legal Rights and the
Privatization of Information Goods
A variety of powerful
economic forces lies behind the current world-wide movement towards transferring
to the market an increasing number of functions that during the first
three-quarters of the twentieth century were assumed by governments in the
industrially advanced societies. The
fiscal pressures to limit public patronage of institutions and activities concerned
with the generation and distribution of knowledge are only one element within
that broader tendency, and a relatively minor one in terms of the claim made on
national economic resources for such purposes. But the ideological pressures seem powerful
nonetheless, for, in the present era the language of private rights and
individual action has acquired renewed potency.
Indeed, the seemingly
inexorable drift towards privatization of all forms of information by extension
of copyright-like protections across a widening field of application, and the
strengthening of the ownership rights conveyed through new legislation and
judicial opinions, has prompted legal scholars to comment upon the ambiguity of
the concept of intellectual property, the asymmetrical definition of the
private (as distinguished from the public) domain, and the rhetorical power of
references to individuals’ “rights” - each of which have been at work in this
process. [20]
The notion of “intellectual
property,” of course, is a purely metaphorical construct, and one that has
swept into fashion only comparatively recently.
During the first half of the twentieth century it was more common for
patents, trademarks and copyrights to be referred to more plainly - as
“industrial property.” In what sense can
one really deem as “intellectual creations” many of the expressive materials
that today are entitled to receive legal protection under copyright laws or
parallel statutes? Do office memoranda
really qualify? What about the tracks
made on a cloth by cats whose feet had been dipped in paint? Or, the images captured on film, or
electronically by CCTV surveillance cameras? Practically any sampling of the results of
reifying the idea of “intellectual property will forcibly bring to mind the
observation that employing a metaphor involves making an internally
contradictory assertion, by likening one thing to another when plainly the two
are not at all the same. [21]
The obvious objective of
giving an “intellectual” spin to such items of property is to try to induce
some greater resonance with the more culturally valued and hence
“protection-worthy” expressions of literary and artistic creativity. But, the main rhetorical coup is achieved by
designating the whole incoherent collection “property.” To speak of “property” automatically inhibits
thoughts of confiscation by the State, while promoting the extension of some
people’s “rights” to ownership, even though that may entail the restriction or
extinction of others’ ability to exercise common access to the goods in
question.
Property rights both
delineate and convey to the holder the legally sanctioned conditions for
excluding others from trespass: they do not establish for others any positive
rights not to be thus excluded. Although
the concept of a distinct sphere demarcated as the “public domain” is well
recognized under conventional intellectual property laws, what it contains is
not defined and legal “rights” to its use are not delineated; “property” is
what is
20. See, particularly, the commentary of Vaver
(2000), which has inspired much of the following. Note that this discussion refers to legal
“property rights,” whereas there is another conceptualization of “rights” that
enables economists to speak of de facto, and even illegal “property
rights.” The latter, however, seems more
closely allied to notions of the “capabilities” and “powers” of economic
agents, rather than to the ideas of justice and equity. Barzel (1989) has
elaborated an interesting transactions cost analysis approach to the economics
of property rights defined in that more comprehensive way. The distinction just made will be seen to be
germane to discussions of “anti-piracy” measures and the utilization of
“self-help” technologies (e.g., encryption) for private enforcement of legal
ownership rights in intellectual property.
21. On metaphors, metanemes and their
rhetorical and epistemological functions, see Johansson (1993).
defined by the law, and the public domain holds the residuum.
Thus, the exemptions permitted for “fair
use” of copyrighted material (under U.S. copyright law and the Berne
Convention) do not convey to researchers, educators or
literary commentators any positive rights to reproduce expressive material
without license from the copyright holder. Instead, they offer simply a legitimate ground
for defense against suits brought for copyright infringement; the rights
to exclude supervene in such cases, however, so that courts generally will
grant injunctive relief to the plaintiff - stopping the publication and
withdrawing materials that are alleged to have infringed her exclusive
copyright. As “fair use” is not then a
legally established “right,” there is nothing in the law that reciprocally
secures reasonable conditions of “fair use” access to legally protected texts
and data for a purpose such as research or evaluation.
There is thus a general
asymmetry in both law and political rhetoric that has favored the broadening of
private rights and the curtailment of the sphere of common entitlements in
regard to conventional, physical assets; and presently it is operating no less
powerfully to encourage the privatizing of the world’s scientific and
technological knowledge base. Part of
this power derives from the irreversibility of changes, which cumulatively
imparts unidirectionality to the process. Removing or restricting the exercise of rights
that already have been granted legal recognition is politically very difficult,
far more so than abrogating customary patterns of usage. Consequently, a ratchet-like mechanism comes
into play in the course of virtually all efforts to codify and harmonize
systems of rights. In international and
interregional negotiations concerned with IPR harmonization, the general level
of protections invariably are harmonized upwards for some of the parties
rather than downwards, because it is politically hazardous for any but the most
autocratic government to be perceived by its citizens as having acquiesced for
whatever purpose in the surrender of “rights” that they already were enjoying.
An obvious impetus behind
recent as well as historical innovations in public policy and institutional
legal and regulatory regimes has been the drive to create conditions that would
promote, or at a minimum facilitate the introduction of market mechanisms where
these previously had little scope for operation. Increasingly, an objective of government-led
initiatives is to actively foster the entry of profit-seeking enterprises into
the production and distribution of goods and services that previously were not
“priced,” and instead were for public provision through a variety of non-market
arrangements. Outwardly at least, there
seem no compelling economic or political reasons why these invigorated forces
favoring further commodification in the domains of
information and “knowledge,” should have emerged at the very same moment in
history as the array of spectacular ICT advances that are rendering data and
information more abundant, and cheaper to process and distribute than ever
before. Indeed, the coincidence of those
two sets of developments might be seen to have been simply an “accident of
history”: the chance conjuncture of the inter-networking phase of the digital
revolution and the ending of the great power conflict of the Cold War,
initiating the global ascendancy of market capitalism, and a widely felt need
for fiscal retrenchment on the part of the governments of the leading
industrial nations.
That is a confluence of
circumstances which, although possibly unrelated in their origins and
fortuitous in their timing, nevertheless are likely to have enduring
consequences that will come to be seen as freighted with historical irony. In contrast with the pre-existing information
distribution regime, the new reproduction technologies - and the opportunities
for by-pass in data transport that digitization of text, images, and sound that
they have rendered economically feasible - removed much of the prospect of being
about to recoup the fixed costs of the infrastructure by selling the (common
carrier) service of transmitting “bits.” Integration into the provision of value-added
services, and protection of the profits of those services by ownership of
copyrightable and non-copyable “content” thus became
the logic of the emerging business regime based upon an enhanced digital
information infrastructure. The alternative
solution, of having the infrastructure provided as a public utility funded from
general revenues, or a mixture of user charges and
tax-financed construction subsidies, seems to run against “the spirit of the
times” and so simply has not received any serious consideration in public
policy circles.
15
In my view, this is an
accident of historical timing: the conjuncture of the ICT revolution with the
1980s fiscal stringency, and the early 1990’s reaffirmation of the ideology of
market capitalism that followed the collapse of Soviet-style socialism. It is hard, indeed, to imagine that earlier in
the twentieth century the recommendation to privatize a major new form of
communications infrastructure would have gained such instant approval as that
which was expressed following the U.S. government’s decision in the early
1990’s to open the Internet for further development by the private sector under
a regime of minimal regulation. Yet
today, claims made on behalf of the academic research community for the
protection of an open space, a “knowledge commons,” are likely to be regarded
as inimical not only to the ideology of the market, but as threatening the
regime through which national and global information infrastructures can be
enhanced - so that the full benefits of broadband digital communications and e-commerce
might be enjoyed by society at large.
Such views, however
misguided, are wedded to immediate private economic interests and therefore
constitute part of the political reality that must be recognized, especially if
successful efforts are to be mounted to check the further commercialization of scientific
data and information. Thus, part of the
reality facing academic science is that there is a need to adjust the IPR
regime to cope with the otherwise de-stabilizing effects of the digital
revolution upon established enterprises in the publishing business; and another
part is the persistence of fiscal pressures on public agencies. That, in turn, combines readily with private
interests to further the transfer to the private sector the provision of data
and information hitherto undertaken as a public service by state agencies.
Quite evidently the rapid
advances made during the past decade in electronic and optical
telecommunications, and other components of digital network technologies, are
having some profoundly unsettling effects upon the industrial organization and
competitive structure of conventional publishing businesses. The disruptive impacts of these technical
developments upon pre-existing business interests and established institutions are
a familiar feature of the ways in which technological innovation, in the form
of new processes and products, drives economic growth. Joseph Schumpeter (1913) described it as
“creative destruction” - much to the shock of the academic economics establishment
in the Vienna of his early career. Not
surprisingly, then, some “IPR reform” initiatives have essentially been
defensive responses to the disruption of the industrial status quo ante,
seeking to protect existing streams of economic rent from new sources of
competition; whereas other efforts have aimed to adapt the institutional and
legal frameworks in ways that would create profitable applications of new
technologies for competitive purposes.
A goodly part of the
current ferment within legal, business and government policy circles that has
been created by effort to recast and extend national laws and international
conventions governing the protection of intellectual property therefore may be
seen as part and parcel of the defensive manoeuvring
by firms with sunk costs in obsolescent technologies who have found themselves
caught in the gale of creative destruction that has been unleashed by the
digital revolution. It should be
recognized, however, that more systemic opportunity-seeking motives also are at
work. There are respects in which the
newly arising possibilities of exploiting these enhanced technological
capabilities for commercial ends are directly imparting momentum to drive
toward privatization of what was formerly treated as the natural domain of
public knowledge. These underlying
causal connections are particularly interesting, and worthy of closer
examination, if only to establish that they are likely to reassert themselves
and thus to resist piecemeal and sporadic efforts to hold back further
incursions upon the “public knowledge commons” in science and technology.
These developments just
reviewed hardly are the only institutional sequelae
of the technologically driven alteration of costs affecting the
reproduction and transmission of text, images (and voice) communications. But, the restructuring of the legal regimes
relating to patents and copyrights, and the implications those induced
innovations are likely to effect on the organization and conduct of scientific
research and publishing. Indeed, they
seem bound to figure among the more prominent unexpected consequences of the
very same digital
infrastructure technologies that were created by publicly sponsored
scientists and engineers. Unfortunately,
at least some of these repercussions now appear to be detrimental to the
long-term vitality of the practice of “open” science in the world’s academic
research communities. Such an untoward
effect will not follow from the technology itself. It comes, instead, from the lack of appropriate
concern for maintaining a healthy balance between the domain of publicly
supported knowledge production and exchanges, and the sphere in which flourish
private, proprietary R&D and profitable businesses based upon information
goods.
Too much should not be made
of the separation between the spheres in which information-goods are freely
shared, and that in which access to them is tightly controlled by private
profit-seeking agents. At least, it is
important to notice that there is a region in which the two can overlap. Indeed, business publishers actually may find
it possible to enhance their profits by permitting and even facilitating free
sharing of information goods among socially connected producer- and consumer-groups
- that is to say, among bounded entities (such as families, social clubs, and
work-groups) in which membership is limited by conditions other than payment of
fees, and within which there is considerably less heterogeneity of demands for
the goods in question than that which exists in the population at large. Allowing free sharing in this sphere, in
effect, permits self-aggregation of potential customers into collectivities
whose joint “willingness to pay” will significantly excess the sum of the
constituent members’ willingness to pay on for the good or service in question.
[22] In the
context of the present discussion, therefore, it is especially appropriate to
point out that academic scientific research networks are in a sense
paradigmatic of the self-selected producer groupings whose information goods
requirements might be more profitably met by publisher/vendors who permitted,
or actually facilitated free (intra-group) sharing. [23] Viewed from this perspective, the current rush to tighten
the copyright regime and encourage strict enforcement of “anti-piracy”
provisions of all kinds, may at some date in the not-so-distant future come to
be perceived as having been a serious mistake, not only because its
consequences were injurious to the conduct of open science, but because they
were antithetical to the development and exploitation of new and more
profitable business opportunities.
One source of difficulty in
preserving such balance is quite immediately apparent. An attractive short-run strategy of business
development entails utilizing enhanced information processing and
telecommunications in conjunction with the assertion of private property rights
over the mass of publicly provided data and information products. Rather than having to produce wholly new
content for distribution via the new and more effective technical facilities,
an obvious first line of enterprise is to make use of what comes freely and
most readily to hand. Ever since the
introduction of printing with moveable type, the history of new publication and
broadcast media has shown how automatic it is for entrepreneurs to seek first
to draw upon content that was already available in the public domain. Hence, one can expect that this approach will
continue to be tried, exploiting larger and larger portions of the body of
codified scientific knowledge and observational data that has been built up
under public patronage and maintained as a common, readily accessible research
resource. Sometimes the
commercialization of public databases makes good economic sense: because
private firms may have technical or marketing capabilities that would add value
for a variety
22. On the conditions under which publishers’ profits are raised by
permitting free sharing of copyrighted material, see, e.g., Liebowitz
(1985), and Bakos, Bryrijolfsson
and Lichtmani (1999). These contributions represent an important
qualification of the widely asserted claim that digitally assisted, low
marginal cost reproduction encourages “piracy” (unlicensed copying and redistribution)
which must be injurious to copyright holders, and therefore warrants
introduction of stronger protections against all unauthorized copying. See, e.g., Besen (1986); Besen and Kirby
(1989).
23. Moreover, in “the knowledge society” - where collaborative
generation of new ideas and practices is expected to characterized
a larger and larger segment of business activity, the scientific research
network, conceived of as a form of “competence based club,” may become a
paradigm for an economically much larger part of the market for
information-goods that are research inputs.
17
of end users of publicly generated data, whereas
existing government agencies or NGOs lack that competence.
Such was shown to be the
case in regard to the distribution and packaging by commercial weather
information services of data gathered by the U.S. National Oceanic and Atmospheric
Administration (NOAA). [24] But, the possibility of seriously adverse consequences
elsewhere in the national research system, from ill-designed policies and
programs to promote proprietary exploitation of public knowledge resources,
also needs to be recognized. Consider
what ensued in those circumstances from the Reagan Administration’s sponsorship
of the Land-Remote Sensing Commercialization Act (1984), under which the
responsibility for the operations of the Landsat
system of remote sensing satellites was transferred from NOAA management, and a
monopoly on Landsat images was awarded in 1985 to the
Earth Observation Satellite (EOSAT) Company, a joint venture of Hughes and RCA.
The price of Landsat
images immediately rose 10-fold, from $400 per image to $4000. This permitted EOSAT to attract profitable
business from commercial customers and the federal government, although
virtually none from academic and independent researchers. Indeed, the impact of the privatization of Landsat operations upon basic research being conducted by
university groups around the world was quite devastating, as, they suddenly
went from being “data rich” into a condition not of actual “data poverty” so
much as one of data “non-entitlement.” [25]
The EOSAT Co. secured its
monopoly position in the market for satellite images by virtue of being given
physical control over the source of (Landsat) images.
Yet it is equally possible to imagine
that a similarly damaging outcome for academic researchers would follow from
the exercise of the market power that a commercial provider of a scientific
database might gain under intellectual property protection; especially under a
legal regime that granted indefinitely renewable copyright protection to the
database contents, whether or not the data was otherwise copyrightable. It will be seen (from the discussion in the
following section) that such is the import of the European Commission’s
Directive on the Legal Protection of Databases, issued on March 11 1996; and
similar circumstances also might arise under the terms of at least one (H.R.
354) of the two database copyright bills presently being considered for passage
by the U.S. Congress.
6. The European Commission’s Database Directive and
Its Economic Implications
A new and quite unexpected
direct threat to the academic research enterprise in science and engineering
has emerged since the mid-1990’s, as a result of the
extension of sui generis
copyright protection to databases, even to databases containing
non-copyrightable material. This
institutional innovation emerged first in the European Union Directive on the
Legal Protection of Databases (issued March 11, 1996), which directed member
states to create a new broadly comprehensive type of intellectual property that
was free from a number of the important and long-standing limitations and
exceptions traditionally provided by copyright law, in order to safeguard
access to information used in socially beneficial, knowledge-creating
activities such as research and teaching. The EU Database Directive applies equally to
non-electronic and electronic databases, even though, as will be seen, it
originated as a strategic “industrial policy” response to the commercial
development of online (electronic) databases in America.
Further, as a device to
secure international acceptance of the new approach initiated by this directive
(which remains binding upon the member states of the European Union, in the
sense of requiring implementation in each of their national statutes)
reciprocity provisions
24. See National Research Council (1997), pp. 116-124, for material
underlying this and the following discussion.
25. The introduction here of the term “non-entitlement” is a deliberate
allusion to Amartya Sen’s
observation that people starved in the Indian famine of 1918 not because the
harvest was inadequate to feed them, but because the rise in grain prices had
deprived them of “entitlement” to the food that actually was available.
were included. The
latter in effect threatened the commercial creators of databases who were
nationals of foreign states outside the EU with retaliatory infringement of
copyright material in their products, unless their respective governments
became signatories to a World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO) draft
convention on databases which had been framed to embody the essential
provisions of the sui generis
copyright protection established under the1996 EU Directive. [26]
The European Commission’s
strategy succeeded in setting in motion an Administration-initiated legislative
response in the U.S. Congress, which has now led to two competing draft
statutes being actively debated. The
response began in May 1996 with the introduction at the behest of the U.S.
Patent and Trademark Office of House of Representatives of a bill, H.R. 3531,
short-titled the “Database Investment and Intellectual Property Antipiracy Act of 1996.” This first and ill-considered rush to
legislate soon encountered opposition from the U.S. academic research community
and non-commercial publishers of scientific information. But although that attempt
proved unavailing, the legislative genie has been let out of the bottle, with
the result that the 104th Congress presently has before it two further pieces
of proposed legislation. The
first of these is “The Collections of Information Antipiracy
Act,” H.R. 345, which was introduced in January 1999 and represents a re-incarnation
of the quite pernicious approach taken in the original Administration-inspired
legislative proposal in 1996. A second
bill, “The Consumer and Investors Access to Information Act,” H.R. 1858, was
introduced in May 1999, and contains provisions protecting access to database
information that are rather more responsive to the objections raised during
1997 against H.R. 3531.
This is not the occasion
for a careful analysis of the proposed database legislation pending in the U.S.
But there are several useful points to
be made by looking more closely at the origins, and the economic implications
for the future of scientific data production and exchange, of the institutional
initiative that may be held immediately responsible for provoking this American
response: the final text of the European Directive on the Legal Protection of
Databases of March 11 1996. [27]
The impetus for the
Commission of the European Communities’ proposal of a sui
generis or ad hoc extension of copyright
protection to databases grew out of a number of EU member countries’ adoption,
in varying degrees, of policies for commercializing the publication government-generated
data. [28] As part of the process of formulating an overall
strategy for information technologies known as the Information Market Policy
Action (IMPACT) program - which was started by the Commission in the late 1980s
under Commissioner Martin Bangemann - a survey was
undertaken that revealed that the growth of the database business in Europe was
lagging, and those in the field felt themselves to be at
26. The 1996 draft was entitled: “Basic Proposal for the Substantive
Provisions of the Treaty on Intellectual Property in Respect of Databases...”, WIPO Doc. CRNR/DC, Geneva, August 30. It has been pointed out that in this regard,
as well as in others, the EU Directive called for a departure from the
principle of administering commercial laws on a “national treatment” basis,
under which a country’s domestic laws (whether for intellectual property
production, or unfair business practices) should treat foreign nationals like
one of the country’s citizens. The
principle of national treatment is embodied in Article 3 of the TRIPs Agreement, as well as more generally in the Paris
Convention (on patents and trademark protection) and the Berne Convention (on
copyright protection). Objections to this
departure were recorded in the testimony of the General Counsel of the U.S.
Department of Commerce (Andrew J. Pincus), in the 106th
Congress House Hearings on HR. 1858 (1999) section F.
27. Much of the discussion here draws upon the narrative material
presented in National Research Council (1997) pp.l46-l6l.
28. Such commercialization is contrary to the policy stance of the US,
where the right of the federal government to copyright its data has been withheld
by Congress from the early days of the Republic, and tradition has favored
citizens’ full and open access to non-military public sector information. The federal government does, however, file for
copyrights on its publication in other national juridictions.
19
some disadvantage vis-à-vis American firms. The latter had got off to an earlier start and
already had taken a large part of the world market, yet continued to expand
relatively rapidly. Remedies were
proposed, starting with the harmonization of copyright laws within a single,
integrated European market, and then combined with higher levels of IPR
protection tailored to the needs of potential investors in database production.
This proposal rather
paralleled the arguments heard in World Bank circles during the early 1990’s,
regarding the positive effects on direct foreign investment of the introduction
of a stronger intellectual property regime in the developing, recipient
economy. But here the argument was not
that intellectual property protection was needed to induce investors to be
willing to disclose their technologies; rather it was that the combination of a
new form of copyright monopoly and international reciprocity clauses would
permit European firms to seize and hold their domestic markets, whilst being left
to garner some export earnings from the sale of such data abroad for their own
official government statistical products. Privatization of the government’s role in
collecting and distributing data was thus seen as another supporting policy to
encourage entry of new database generators, as well as possibly providing
income streams that would offset the shrinking availability of public funds for
R&D. Here one may read the influence
of the now ascendant “wealth creation” rationale that guides much European
science and technology policy.
A study of comparative law
revealed that at the time the Nordic countries already were experimenting with
short-term, copyright-like protection of non-copyrightable compilations (known
as the Nordic catalogue rule). They had
taken this step with a view to curbing commercial piracy without extending full
copyright production to borderline literary productions that lacked creative
authorship. In 1992 the Commission
embraced this idea by drafting an innovative Directive to protect such
databases in electronic form. The
Council of Ministers and the European Parliament adopted an amended version in
July 1995, which extended the protection to databases in print media as well. It was this amended draft that issued as the
final Directive on March 111996.
One rather remarkable
aspect of these proceedings in the European Commission reflected the
pre-committed policy position advanced by the 1994 report on Europe and the
global information society, prepared for the European Council by a
“High-Level Group” under the chairmanship of Commissioner Martin Bangemann. [29] Intellectual property was embraced as central to the “Vision” of
the Information Society projected in the Bangemann
Report (1994: Ch. 3):
“In this global information market place, common rules
must be agreed and enforced by everyone. Europe has a vested interest in ensuring
that protection of IPRs receives full attention and
that a high level of protection is maintained.”
This commitment sufficed in
place of any inquiries as to whether recourse to sui
generis copyright protection really was needed to
stimulate European investment in database creation. How American database vendors had managed to
surge so far ahead of Europe in this field, especially without the benefit of
any special copyright protection, does not appear to have been a point on which
the High-Level Group sought empirical enlightenment. Indeed, only the year before the draft
Directive appeared, the U.S. Supreme Court decision in Feist
v. Rural Telephone (1991) had removed the remaining shreds of legitimacy
draped around the argument that the producer of a database was entitled to the
protections of copyright law on the basis of the sheer “sweat of the brow”
effort invested in the activity of compilation, whether or not any significantly
original contribution had been made to its contents. [30]
29. See Vaver (1999) for the broader context
of European innovation policy approaches within which recent copyright
directives have been developed.
30. The importance of the “sweat of the brow” argument for the legal
protection of database investors has tended to be exaggerated. Both before and following the 1991 Feist ruling, copyright applied to the original selection, [co-ordination, and arrangement of data within a
database; many defendants in the U.S. therefore have been found liable for
copyright infringement since 1991. It
has been claimed by industry proponents of sui
generis legislative protection that comprehensive
electronically stored databases could not meet the standard set by copyright
law, and such arguments conceivably may have influenced the EC’s High-Level
Experts Group, members of the European Parliament, or advisers to the Council
of Ministers. The comprehensive
character of the compilation was said to imply that no “selection” was made by
the database author; and the digital nature of the contents supposedly meant
that rather than having been “arranged” by the compiler, the data were
“arranged” by the user employing a search engine. But apart from cases involving a
comprehensive electronically stored database consisting of telephone listing,
U.S. courts have not issued rulings that would confirm such fears. Most commercially valuable databases contain
many linked fields, and the selection and arrangement of data in these is a
sufficiently complex task to constitute some minimal level of creativity on the
part of the author. U.S. copyright law
clearly prevents the wholesale copying of such (non-trivial) database
structures, and thus affords their publishers significant protection even in
the post-Feist era.]
HHC: [bracketed] displayed on page 21 of original.
Had they looked more
closely at the prevailing business practices, the High-Level Group would have
discovered that a wide variety of other appropriation devices was available and
was being successfully deployed by U.S. database businesses. [31]
In the case of the so-called “full text” databases,
which often consist entirely of copyrighted documents, the contents do not lose
their protected status by virtue of having been incorporated into a database. Another appropriation device available under
existing law is the use of copyrighted enhancements: databases frequently are
sold in a package along with advanced software. Because software is copyrightable (and in some
instances patentable), would-be copiers must either try to market a product
that is less useful, or make their own investment in developing search tools to
package with the copied contents.
Furthermore, technical database firms in the U.S. were availing
themselves of a variety of “self help” protections against free-riding. Custom and semi-custom databases prepared for
a small number of users provide virtually automatic protection against third
parties, and, more generally, contracts between the owners of such databases
and their customers which limit the latter’s right to use and/or disclose the
contents to third parties are enforceable as trade secrets, even where the
underlying information and data cannot qualify for statutory protection.
Where information was
distributed to larger numbers of customers, the industry availed itself of the
use of “shrinkwrap” and “clickwrap”
licences, search-only and password protected
websites, and the frequent updating of contents, editing and enhancements of
search facilities - all of which are especially valuable to researchers in
rapidly changing branches of science. Besides these means, Maujrer’s
(1999) survey of industry practice found that “a significant number of products
are sold without any protection at all, sometimes for comparatively high
prices.” The explanation offered is that
large vendors can afford to circulate catalogues that enable them to reach a
small number of customers who are prepared to pay high prices for comparatively
obscure titles, whereas the smaller would-be copiers cannot afford the expense
of trying to bring their wares to the attention of those same purchasers. Thus, there was little if any substance to the
rationale that was offered for issuing the EU Database Directive, namely, that
special copyright protection was necessary to “level the playing field” so that
European database creators could compete on less disadvantageous terms with
their American counterparts.
It seems evident that few
if any representatives among the affected basic scientific research communities
in Europe, and few among those responsible for the direction of national
science policies in the member countries, were engaged in the proceedings that
gave rise to the recommendations of the High-Level Experts Group. Considerable attention in such quarters was being
focused at the time upon the intellectual property issues involved in the
transition to electronic publishing of scientific and engineering journals. [32] But far less notice
31. See Maurer (1999): pp. 19-21.
32 The history of efforts to address these issues, and the divisions of
opinion within the European science communities that emerged in regard to “fair
use,” have been examined recently by Burnett (1999).
21
was taken - either elsewhere within the Commission or
outside it - of the adverse side-effects upon scientific data access and
exchanges that might result from the radical legal proposal that Mr. Bangemann’s Directorate was entertaining as part of its
strategy to promote the development of the database industry in Europe. [33]
The EC did not set out to
directly challenge the traditional resistance to protecting information that
was not copyrightable, by maintaining that there was no natural domain in which
non-copyrightable material might remain. Rather, it sought to correct what it saw to be
unsatisfactory disincentives for investment in electronic database production. Those arose, in its view, from the absence (no
more in Europe and elsewhere, to be sure) of “unfair competition legislation”
that would safeguard businesses from having their database products accessed or
copied at a fraction of the costs necessary to design and produce them. The Commission’s immediate aim, therefore, was
to prevent “unfair extraction” of the contents of databases, subject to
specifying some user’s rights and safeguards of the public interest in free
competition. But, in the drafting and
redrafting process, the public interest safeguards came to be de-emphasized in
favor of stronger protection of private investor interests.
This extension of property
rights over “content should be seen as not an idiosyncratic and anomalous
outcome of the closed proceedings of the European Council of Ministers that
produced the Common Position draft of 10 July, 1995. It is, rather, part and parcel of a much more
widespread governmental response to the challenge of funding the infrastructure
of an enhanced national or regional information system. Many public databases, containing information
about government agencies and facilities, civil law statutes and commercial
codes, judicial rulings, governmental census and survey statistics, technical
reference data and standards specifications, indeed, too many to enumerate
here, make up key software elements of a modern nation’s information
infrastructure. But, as I have remarked
previously, the basic governmental response to the challenge of enhancing the
communications infrastructure for the digital information age increasingly has
been to derogate to the private sector greater and greater responsibilities for
bearing the fixed capital costs, and then hastening to endow private parties
with whatever new profit opportunities might induce them to undertake the
necessary investment of resources.
What has been the
consequence in the instance at hand? A
rapid review of the main features of the EC’s Database Directive of 1996
highlights the following problematic points: [34]
- The Directive’s sui
generis approach departs from the long
established principles of intellectual property law by removing the distinction
between protection of expression and protection of ideas, a distinction that is
central in US copyright law and was embodied in the TRIPS agreement adopted by
the WTO.
- Compilers of databases in the EU will now be able to
assert ownership and demand payment for licensing the use of content, which
already is in the public domain, including material that otherwise could not be
copyright-protected. In complying with
the Directive, member states will not be providing any specific incentives for
the generation of new database content (such as scientific data and
information, for example), as distinguished from new compilations. Nor can it be thought that copyrights in
databases are being granted as part of a social bargain, in exchange for the
public disclosure of material that hitherto was not revealed.
- A second distinction fundamental in copyright law, that between original expressive matter and
pre-existing expressive matter, has been discarded by
33. Remarkably, the view that such a strategy for the “information
industries” would not have any seriously problematic repercussions for other
parts of the European innovation system appears to have been shared by Madame
Edith Cresson, who at that time had responsibility on the EC for science and
technology policy.
34. The following draws upon the documented legal analysis in National
Research Council (1997), pp. 148-153.
language of the Directive, because the latter fails to attach
any legal significance to the difference between expressive matter that already
exists in the public domain, and matter that is original and newly disclosed. Domestic laws and national courts that
reaffirm this omission in effect will allow a database maker to qualify for
renewal of the 15-year term of exclusive rights over the database as a whole -
by virtue of having made a “significant investment” in updates, additions,
revisions. [35]
- Strict limitations upon
re-use of database contents are imposed by the Directive, requiring third party
regeneration or payment for licenses to extract such material. This would inhibit integration and
recombination of existing scientific database contents with new material to
provide more useful, specialized research resources.
- But regardless of whether
or not it is possible in theory to regenerate the raw contents of a database
from publicly available sources, under the terms of the Directive, investors in
database production can always deny third parties the right to use pre-existing
data in value-added applications, even when the third parties are willing to
pay royalties on licenses for such use. It
would therefore be possible for an initial database producer simply to block
subsequent creation of new, special-purpose databases which reproduced parts of
existing compilations, wherever the regeneration of such data de novo was
infeasible or terribly costly (as in the case of years of remote-sensing satellite
observations, or data-tracks from high energy particle collision detectors, or
multi-year bibliographic compilations of scientific publications and citations
thereto).
- Where a database maker
also held the exclusive rights to license previously copyright-protected
publications, it would be entirely proper under the terms of the Directive to
refuse third parties licenses in that material, while incorporating it within a
database protected under the terms of the EC Directive. There are no compulsory licensing provisions
under the Berne Convention on copyrights, and these are likewise excluded under
the TRIPS Agreement. By following suit
and excluding conditions for compulsory licensing, as well as omitting to
provide remedies for abuse of the legal protections newly accorded to database
investors, the Directive opens the door for the construction of indefinitely
renewable monopolies in both non-re-generatable and
non-re-generatable scientific data.
- The Directive abandons
the principle of “fair use” for research, as distinct from extraction and use
of data for purposes of “illustration in teaching or research.” How “illustrative use” is to be interpreted
remains ill defined, pending some infringement litigation that would provide
opportunity for a court ruling in the matter. But the current consensus among IPR scholars
is that “illustration” falls far short of the normal scope of research use of
copyrighted material. Such an
interpretation is consistent with the fact that
The absence of fair use
exclusions for research (and research training) creates the prospect of a
two-way squeeze on public sector funded research programs, as the costs of
obtaining commercially supplied data are likely to rise. The 10-fold rise in the unit prices of
remote-sensing satellite images that immediately followed the privatization of
LANSAT satellite operations in 1985, and its withering effects upon
university-based research projects,
35. See EC Directive on Databases, note 52, articles 7(1), providing an
initial 15-year term from the date of completion; 7(2) extending protection for
an additional 15 years if the database “is made available to the public in
whatever manner” before the initial term expires; 7(3) allowing 15-year
renewals for “[a]ny substantial change, evaluated
qualitatively or quantitatively, to the contents of a database... from the
accumulation of successive additions, deletions or alterations, which… result
in... a substantial new investment.” Under U.S copyright only the additions and
revisions themselves - which would be considered as “derivative work” from the
prior original expressive matter - would be entitled to fresh legal protection.
23
might well be recalled in this connection. [36] Continuing pressures for cuts in government
budgets, taken in combination with the priority that tends to be accorded to
near-term applications-oriented research vis-à-vis exploratory science, is
likely to encourage derogation to commercial database generators of the
function of compiling, updating and publishing databases that were created by,
and remain of continuing relevance for basic public sector research. There is a two-fold risk in this situation:
one is the threat to data quality in the separating of the database creation
and maintenance from the scientific expertise of the research community that
creates and uses the data; the other is the resulting squeeze on public
research resources, as already restrictive appropriations would have to be
spent on purchasing data and database licenses.
I should not leave this
discussion without emphasizing that these threats to the vitality of public
sector science and especially to university-based research have not been
confined to the European policy scene. Indeed,
they soon manifested themselves in the U.S., and, seen from the vantage-point
developed here, the legislation introduced in the House of Representatives in
1996 was still more radical and pernicious in its proposal of a new regime of
protection for hitherto non-copyright-able data. It was in large measure
reactive to the European Directive, which includes reciprocity provisions to
which the U.S. Administration was eager to respond, but it soon attracted
industrial backing, including that from commercial publishers. The Administration proposal that went to the
Congress and was introduced as H.R. 3125 thus followed the EU Directive’s weak
language regarding exclusions for “fair use.” Similarly, it carried provisions for
retaliatory government policies of imposing charges for publicly generated
database material upon foreign users, particularly where foreign governments
imposed copyright protection on data they were producing.
These innovations were
tantamount to the outright abandonment of long-established features of both
European and Anglo-American copyright law. Collections of data, including the relatively
unstructured or unprocessed collections of primary interest to scientists have
never fitted comfortably within either of those IPR regimes. Behind this traditional resistance to making
them “protected property” lies the concern that facts
and ideas constitute building blocks of intellectual discourse, and
consequently should not be removed from the public domain. Nor is there a sound economic rationale for
seeking to have them priced and exchanged through the market in the manner of
other, physical inputs that are used in the conduct of scientific
investigations. Unlike ordinary
commodities that may be used to make other commodities, ideas and data are not
exhausted by their use in the generation of still other ideas, as has already
been noted.
Therefore, it is difficult
to accept the logic of the position taken in 1997 by Laura Tyson in her support
of the Administration-inspired database copyright protection bill (H.R. 3125). The former Chairman of the Council of Economic
Advisors, in a privately commissioned report by Heller and Tyson (1999), argued
that it would be economically inefficient to introduce a subsidy for academic
research use at the expense of commercial database vendors - and suggested that
such would be the effect of inserting adequate “fair use” exceptions into the
bill. Instead, Heller and Tyson proposed
that the problems that database copyright protection might create for
university-based scientists should be addressed directly, by having the government
expand research grant budgets enough to enable publicly funded investigators to
pay the charges required by providers of these research inputs, in the same way
that they had to pay for equipment, materials and laboratory facilities, and
research assistants.
But, the gambit of basing
such arguments on the alleged inefficiency of preferentially pricing access to
information goods that are used for research purposes must fail utterly in this
context. This is so because what is
being proposed by the legislation is not the pricing of ordinary commodity
inputs, nor even pricing of information at the extremely low marginal cost of
distributing copies of the database. Rather,
the claim is that since information is costly to assemble in database form,
business firms should be allowed to recoup those (fixed)
36. See the discussion in section 4, above.
development costs by charging whatever they wish. It should then be seen that the subsidy in
this picture is the one that is being offered in the form of legal rights to
the exclusive ownership of database contents, including ownership rights over
material that otherwise would have remained in the public domain. On what grounds should the government create
legal protection for a private monopoly that may be exercised over a public
good that may be used to produce still other public goods of the same kind,
thereby raising the costs of providing something that the market systematically
tends to under-supply?
Happily, in the U.S. the
first and second rounds of legislative effort failed to insert any of these
novel and dubious contrivances into the fabric of intellectual property law. It is difficult to say precisely how great a
role in the initial mobilization of opposition (against H.R. 3153) should be
attributed to the fact that on the Western side of the Atlantic Ocean the
leading scientific journals are published by non-profit scientific
organizations, such as the American Astronomical Society, the American Physical
Society, and the American Chemical Society, and by state and private university
presses. Their voices were prominent in
the counter-lobbying that was swiftly organized against the sui
generis protections proposed for database
producers. The contrast between that and
the situation prevailing in Europe is quite striking: there the business of publishing
scientific journals is in the hands of an oligopoly.
Nevertheless, the
representatives of the academies and professional scientific societies were not
left to stand alone. A significant
source of opposition to the features that closely mimicked those of the E. C.
Directive emerged also from some producers of directories and kindred database
products, as well as firms whose information services relied upon the
construction of massive amounts of data gathered from the public domain. [37] Having, created profitable businesses without relying on
protections for their products, these firms voiced the concern that they soon
might find themselves facing monopolists in the markets for their essential
informational inputs, or in a race with new entrants seeking to secure
exclusive rights to use the uncopyrighted materials
that were embedded among the contents of their own database products.
One further remark may be
added on the contrasting situations in Europe and America, regarding the
political resistance of their respective academic research to these legislative
encroachments upon the “knowledge commons.” With the exception of the European Science
Foundation, and a small number of rather new organizations, such as Academia
Europa, professional scientific societies have
remained fragmented along national lines within the European Union; since
academic research funding is drawn overwhelmingly from national ministries
rather than from the EU’s Programmes,
neither the respective national scientific bodies nor those in government
positions responsible for science policy devote close monitoring and lobbying
efforts to the progress of new Directive being drafted in Brussels and
Luxembourg, or to the proceedings of the European Parliament in Strasbourg. By contrast, the long history of federal government
funding for academic research has served to fix the attention of all who are
concerned with matters touching science and science policy upon Washington,
D.C., even though the research funding flows through the nation’s private and
state-supported universities. Undoubtedly
this has contributed to the closer integration and greater political
sophistication, which the American scientific establishment displays in
mobilizing co-ordinated lobbying campaigns on issues
of professional concern.
One thus may understand why
in Europe the research community’s capacity remains comparatively weak, when it
comes to mounting any very significant resistance to the unbalancing effects of
ill-conceived industrial policy initiatives upon the region’s science and
technology-based system of innovation. Yet,
it would be far from safe to expect that lacking the vision and support of
enlightened governmental leaders, either of these regions’ research communities
will be capable of defending the Republic of Open Science against future
pressures to privatize the knowledge commons. Where, then, does that leave the prospects for
37. See, e.g., U.S. Congress, House Hearings (1999), for material
submitted by the Association of Directory Publishers (p.88-90), supporting the
more limited forms of protection offered under H.R.1858; and testimony of Matthew
Rightmire, Director of Business [)evelopment,
Yahoo! Inc. (p.30-34).
25
the growth of scientific and technological research
capabilities among the developing countries?
7. What Is To Be Done? Protecting for Open Science Research in the
Digital Age
When considering the
available courses of action to counter threats to the pursuit of knowledge
arising from recent innovations intended to strengthen intellectual property
protections, distinctions of two kinds help to simplify the discussion,
although not the problems that need to be addressed. Firstly, there is an obvious difference
between the altered terms and the scope of statutory intellectual property
protections, on the one hand, and on the other hand, legislative steps designed
to reinforce the use of technologies of “self help” that enable copyright
owners to more perfectly control the dissemination of digital content (whether
that is legally protected or not). A
second distinction has to be drawn between the situation of countries where
legislative innovations affecting intellectual property may be under
consideration, and those cases in which such statutes already are faits acomplis - so
that the questions of practical interest concern implementation and
enforcement.
For most of the nations of
the world, the appropriate recommendations in regard to both the technological
and the legal measures that would restrict access to digital data used for
research and training would seem to follow Nancy Reagan’s admonition to youths
who are offered the opportunity to experiment with addictive drugs: “Just say
‘No’!” It is relevant that this option
remains one that is open to all the countries, developed and developing alike,
that are signatories to the TRIPS Agreement, and, of course to those who have
not yet joined the WTO. To date, at
least, there is no international convention in force for the legal protection
of databases and the articles of the TRIPS Agreement do not pertain to database
protection per se. Thus, unless a
case were successfully to be made for interpreting the sui
generis protections for databases created by the
EC Directive of March 11, 1996 as somehow being covered under copyright,
nothing in the TRIPS agreements would oblige other nations to follow the
(misdirected) leaders in this particular regard. Such an interpretation, moreover, would be
utterly tendentious in view of the numerous respects in which the terms of the
EC Database Directive has been seen to deviate from the principles embraced by
national and international copyright law.
Much the same general
position may be advanced in regard to the possible products of the legislative
drive to provide legal reinforcement for technological measures of “self help”
on the part of copyright owners. As has
been noted (in section 4, above), the U.S. Digital Millennium Copyright Act
(1998) includes language making it illegal to furnish - whether by importation
or manufacture, and whether by sale or free distribution - all means of circumventing
“any technological measure that effectively controls access” to a copyrighted
work. As dubious, and in some respects
as counter-productive as these sections of the DMCA have been found to be, by
both legal and technical experts, [38] it remains quite conceivable that an effort will be
made to press other countries into following suit. In an immediate sense, however the issue in
this case is not one of legal principle, but instead belongs to the wider and
unresolved debate about the feasibility and desirability of uniform international
standards of enforcement of intellectual property rights.
Nothing presently compels countries
that are signatory to the TRIPS Agreement to arrive at uniformity in the degree
of enforcement of their intellectual property laws. It is true that the international conventions
and laws governing patents, trademarks, copyrights, trade
38. On the question of “counter-productive” effects, Dam (1998) notes
the testimony by cyptography experts to the effect
that the wording of the 1998 DMCA (U.S. Code, 17, §1201) would make it illegal
even to devise and distribute algorithms used in testing encryption systems by
trying to defeat them., and, more generally would greatly impede research aimed
at making such devices cheap and faster to apply. This point nicely recapitulates the larger
theme that what the would-be protectors of technological innovation most
frequency fail to grasp is that information is an input in the process of
generating new knowledge.
secrets, industrial designs, semiconductor mask works, and
still protections, all must be “effectively implemented and enforced” by each
of the nations belonging to the WTO. Nevertheless,
the term “effectively” remains subject to considerable variations in
interpretation. [39] In addition, the Agreement explicitly recognizes several
bases for exemptions from the provisions made for protection of the rights of
owners of intellectual property, including appeal to “fair use” or “public
interest” (Articles 13, 17,24,27:2, 30 and 37). It may be argued, therefore, that inasmuch as
national governments under the Agreement retain the right to create a haven for
“fair use” of protected intellectual property in the public interest, their
ability to effectively exercise that right would be impeded by requiring that
they prevent their own nationals from circumventing unilaterally imposed access
blocking technologies in order to avail themselves of those “fair use”
exemptions for those very same scientific research and training purposes.
The preceding remarks
obviously apply to the situation in which the developing economies find
themselves with respect to intellectual property protections that would have
seriously inhibited worthy, “public interest” activities, had not the latter
gained statutory exemptions under the laws’ provisos for “fair use.” It remains an interesting question as to
whether its sphere of applicability extends still farther: could it also
encompass retroactive remedial legislative actions on the part of the
economically advanced member states of the EU that have not yet implemented the
EC Directive on the Legal Protection of Databases in their national laws? Whereas some countries, such as the United
Kingdom, were quick to implement the Directive without entering any exceptions
or liberalizing interpretations, others European states, such as the
Netherlands as well as Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, Spain, have not rushed
to comply with its terms. This has
opened a window for attempts to modify the Directive’s force by suitable
interpretations in the way it is implemented. But, rather than leaving it to individual
members to undertake to ameliorate the harm that a literal acceptance and
enforcement of the text of the Directive might do to the scientific research
community in Europe, it would be far more satisfactory for the EC to now
propose a “harmonized” set of fair use exemptions, as a minimal remedial step.
That solution, however, is
most unlikely to emerge spontaneously, not even in the wake of the departure of
EC Commissioner Bangemann, and the scandal-prompted
reforms undertaken by the new leadership of EC President Roman Prodi; some very considerable amount of political pressure
would have to be brought to bear upon the Commission, and a coalition formed
among the smaller member states who have yet to implement the Directive would
seem to be among the few plausible ways in which such pressure could
materialize. Yet, in view of the
politically fragmented condition of Europe’s basic science research communities,
the prospects of an effective coalition emerging would remain rather remote
unless it were to be energized by business corporations similar to those in the
U.S. who have lobbied actively against counterpart database legislation. The political economy of the question,
therefore is likely to turn not upon the longer-run implications for science
and technology in Europe as the logic of economic analysis might dictate, but
instead upon whether or not there exists a significant section of European
industry that comes to perceive a direct and immediate source of harm to their
economic fortunes, in the extraordinary nature of the protections allowed by
the EC’s Database Directive.
According to the American writer
and wit, Mark Twain, “the man who would rid the world of a cancer is not
obliged to put something in its place.” Nevertheless,
the reality of the situation is that in the wake of the EC initiative to
legally protect databases, regardless of whether or not there was empirical
evidence to suggest that such measures were required for the growth of the
database industry in Europe, this particular protection genie has got out of
the bottle and won’t be stuffed back into it completely. What this means is that remediation cannot
simply take the form of a return to the status quo ante. As some alternative recommendations for
intellectual property protection in the market for scientific databases are in
order, I should not conclude the discussion without considering these, however
briefly.
39. See Reichmnan (1998) on the interpretation
of the enforcement articles included in Part III of the TRIPS Agreement, and
the survey of implementation issues in Keely (2000).
27
In the view of most
economists, the “first best” allocation system in situations where goods are
produced with high fixed costs but far lower marginal costs, is to apply what
is known as the “Ramsey pricing” rifle. This
fits the case of information products such as scientific publication and data,
where the first-copy costs are very great in relationship to the negligible
unit costs of copies. Ramsey pricing in
essence amounts to price discrimination between users whose demands are
inelastic and those users for whom the quantity purchased is extremely
price-sensitive. The former class of
buyers therefore will bear high prices without curtailing the quantity
purchased of the goods in question, and hence not suffer great reductions in
consumption utility on that account, whereas the low prices offered to those in
the second category will spare them the burden of economic welfare reducing
cutbacks in their use of the good.
The case might then be made
for treating scholars and public sector, university-based researchers as having
highly elastic information and data demands. Such a characterization would follow from
considering that this category of knowledge-workers is employed on projects
that have fixed budget allocations from public (or non-profit) entities,
organizations that are expected to promote the interests of society at large. Since there is strong complementarity
between their data and information requirements, on the one hand, and on the
other resources they use in their research, the effects of raising the real
price of this input are tantamount to sharply reducing the quantity of useful
work that such projects can accomplish so long as their budgets remain fixed. Obviously, there is no workable economic or
political mechanism that would serve to “index” the nominal value of public
research budgets on the prices of commercially provided data. Even were such mechanisms to be found,
commitment to implement them on the part of the rich societies would most
likely result in pricing the use of scientific information and data beyond the
reach of many poorer societies. The
general conclusion of this line of reasoning is simple: statutes that would
establish legal ownership rights for compilers of scientific and technological
databases also should include provisions mandating compulsory licensing of
scientific database contents at marginal costs (of data extraction and
distribution) to accredited individuals and research institutions.
Of course, a second-best
version of such a policy would be to grant researchers (and educators) broad
“fair use” exemptions from the legal enforcement of database owner’s rights,
dispensing with recovery of marginal costs except where special, value-adding
facilities were used to extract the contents from protected databases. One reason against dispensing entirely with
marginal cost charges is that it may well be the case that marginal extraction
and copying costs might be lower for the database owner than for the research
user, but, in the absence of quoted prices for the service, research groups may
not be aware of this and so waste time and resources in performing tasks that
could be more efficiently undertaken by the commercial database firm. In other words, allowing users to “do it for
themselves” could deny both parties the benefits of the economies of scale and
scope as were available. On the other
side of the argument, it would be desirable to limit the incentives for
database producers to bundle unwanted and costly extraction and reproduction
services with the contents of their database, including services whose costs
cannot be readily established and which give rise to opportunities for
cross-subsidization among different classes of users.
Compulsory licensing has
further attractions as a remedy in this context. No protections are provided in the 1996
Database Directive against the abusive exploitation of market power arising in
cases of sole supply of data; or where high set-up costs tend to preclude
competitive entry into niche markets already occupied by early commercial
database generators. The obvious remedy
here would be to stipulate conditions (derived in accord with the principles
underlying existing competition laws) that would trigger the “regulatory”
imposition of compulsory licensing of database contents at the marginal costs
of data provision. Such provisions would
not be inconsistent with the TRIPS Agreement, Part II of
which (under Article 40) sets out conditions under which
anti-competitive licensing practices that are shown to prevent dissemination of
a technology may be restricted. [40]
But the foregoing modest
proposals are just the beginning of what must become a more intense discussion,
involving participants drawn from many disciplines in the sciences, legal
scholars and business lawyers, representatives of the affected industries and
policy-makers from the developed and developing countries alike. There is much
to do to protect the vitality of the global science system of open
collaboration, and the time to do it has become short.
40. See Keeley (2000) pp. 6-7
29
Abbate,
Janet Ellen, 1999: Inventing the Internet, Cambridge MA: The MIT Press.
Annerstedt,
Jan, 1994: “Measuring science, technology, and innovation,” Ch. 3 in The
Uncertain Quest: Science, Technology and Development, J.-J. Salomon, F. R. Sagasti, and C. Sachs-Jeantet,
eds., Tokyo and New York: United Nations University Press.
Bakos, Yannis, Erik Brynjolfsson and
Douglas Lichtman, 1999: “Shared information goods,”
University of Chicago Law and Economics Working Paper No. 67 (2nd Series),
February.
Bangemann
Report, 1994: Europe and the Global Information Society: Recommendations to
the European council, 26 May.
Barash, Eyal H., 1997: “Experimental uses, patents, and scientific
progress,” Northwestern University Law Review, 91.
Barzel, Yoram, 1989: Economic Analysis of Property Rights, Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Berners-Lee, Timothy, 1999: Weaving the Web: the Past, Present and
Future of the World Wide Web by its Inventor, London: Orion Business Books.
Besen, Stanley
M., 1986: “Private copying, reproduction costs, and the supply of intellectual
property,” Information Economics and Policy, 5(2).
Besen, Stanley
M. and Sheila M. Kiiby, 1989: “Private copying, appropriability and optimal copyright royalties,” Journal
of Law and Economics, 32: pp. 255ff.
CERN, 1997: “Where the Web was born,” European Organization for Nuclear
Research (CERN), Geneva, 3rd December.
Dam, Kenneth W., 1998: “Self-help in the digital jungle,” University
of Chicago Law and Economics Working Paper No. 59, (August).
Dam, Kenneth W., 1999: “Intellectual property and the academic
enterprise,” University of Chicago Law and Economics Working Paper No.
68, (February).
Dasgupta, Partha and Paul A. David, 1987: “Information disclosure and
the economics of science and technology”, Ch. 16 in Arrow and the Ascent of
Modern Economic Theory, G. Feiwel, (ed.), New
York: New York University Press: pp. 519-542.
Dasgupta, Partha and Paul A. David, 1994: “Toward a new economics of
science”, Research Policy, vol. 23: pp. 487-521.
David, Paul A., 1993: “Knowledge, Property and the System Dynamics of
Technological Change,” in Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on
Development Economics:1992, (published as a
Supplement to the World Bank Economic Review), (L. Summers and S. Shah,
eds.), Washington, DC.: International Bank for Reconstruction and Development,
pp. 215-248.
David, Paul A., 1994: “The evolution of intellectual property
institutions,” in System Transformation:
Eastern and Western Assessments, (Proceedings of the Tenth Congress of the International
Economic Association, Vol.1), A. Aganbegyan, 0. Bogomolov and M. Kaser, (eds.), London: MacMillan,
1994.
David, Paul A., 1998: “Common Agency Contracting and the Emergence of
‘Open Science’ Institutions,” American Economic Review: Papers and
Proceedings, 88(2), May.
David, Paul A., 2000: “The digital technology boomerang: intellectual
property rights protections and the enclosing of the public knowledge “commons”
in science.” Presented at the Innovation Policy Colloquium, New York University
School of Law, 13 April, 2000.
(March).
Eisenberg, Rebecca S., 1989: Patents and the progress of science:
exclusive rights and experimental uses, University of Chicago Law Review, 56.
European Commission, 1999: Transforming European Science through
Information and Communication Technologies, Report by the ETAN Expert
Working Group, DG for Research: Directorate A-RTD Actions: Policy Co-ordination
and Strategy. September.
Gaillard,
Jacques, 1994: “The behaviour of scientists and
scientific communities,” Ch. 6 in The Uncertain Quest. Science,
Technology and Development, J.-J.
Salomon, F. R. Sagasti, and C. Sachs-Jeantet, eds., Tokyo and New York: United Nations University
Press.
Hardin, Garrett, 1968: The tragedy of the commons,” Science, 162:
pp. 1243 ff.
Heller, Michael A., and Rebecca S. Eisenberg, 1998: “Can patents deter
innovation? The anticommons in biomedical research,” Science, 280 (May
1).
Johansson, S. Ryan, 1993: The brain’s software: the natural languages
and poetic information processing,” The Machine as Metaphor and Tool, Herman
Haken, Anders Karlqvist and
Uno Svedin, eds., Berlin:
Springer-Verlag.
Keely, Louise
C., 2000: Pathway from Poverty? Intellectual Property in Developing Countries
(A Report Commissioned by the Intellectual Property Institute), London:
Centre for Economic Performance, London School of Economics and Political
Science, April.
Liebowitz,
Stan J., 1985: “Copying and indirect appropriability:
photocopying of journals”,Journal
of Political Economy, 93 : pp. 945 ff.
Maurer, Stephen M., 1999: “Raw knowledge: protecting technical databases
for science and industry,” A Report Prepared for the National Research
Council Workshop on Promoting Access to Scientific and Technical Data for the
Public Interest. National Academy of Science, Washington D.C., January
14-15.
Moulton, P. M., Joan Young, and J. J. Eberhardt,
1990: Technological advances in instrumentation: impacts on R&D
productivity,” Battelle Institute Working
Paper, Pacific Northwest Laboratory, Richmond, WA.
Naughton,
John, 1999: A Brief History of the Future. the
Origins of the Internet, London: Weidenfeld &
Nicholson.
National Research Council, 1997: Bits of Power. Issues
in Global Access to Scientific Data. Washington, D. C.: National
Academy Press.
National Research Council, 1999: Funding a Revolution. Government
Support for Computing Research, Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press.
National Research Council, 2000: The Digital Dilemma. Intellectual Property
in the Information Age, Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press.
Reichman,
J. H., 1998: “Securing compliance with the TRIPS agreement after US v. India,” Journal
of International Economic Law, 1(4): 585-602.
Tyson, Laura D’Andrea and Edward F. Sherry,
1997: Statutory protection for databases: economic and public policy issues.
(Prepared by the Law and Economics Consulting Group for two international
publishing companies.), September 5th..
U.S. 106th Congress House Hearings, 1999: Subcommittee on
Telecommunications, Trade and Consumer Protection Hearings on HR. 1858 (June
15, 1999), Serial No. 106-49, Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office.
Vaver,
David, 1999: “Copyright in Europe: the good, the bad and the harmonized,” Australian
Intellectual Property Journal, 10(4), November.
31
Vaver,
David, 2000: “On the idea of intellectual property and the growth of copyright
law,” An Inaugural Lecture by the Reuters Professor of Intellectual Property in
the University of Oxford,, Delivered on 17 th May, in the Gulbenkian Lecture
Theatre, Oxford.
Walsh, J.P. and T. Bayma, 1996: “The virtual
college: computer-mediated communications and scientific work”, The
Information Society, 12, pp. 343 ff.
32