The Competitiveness of Nations in a Global Knowledge-Based Economy
Alfred D.
Chandler, Jr.
Decision Making and Modern Institutional
Change
Journal of Economic
History, 33 (1
The Tasks of Economic
History, Mar., 1973,
1-15.
Content
HHC: titles added to numbered
sections
WHEN I began to prepare this talk, I recalled that the
first such address I ever listened to helped persuade me to become an economic
historian. It was Herbert Heaton’s
delightful “The Making of an Economic Historian,” which began with a bit of
elegant doggerel. If a discipline
could produce such an address, I decided that this association was certainly
worth joining. But alas, I was
optimistic. I was to hear more
erudite presidential addresses but few so witty and informative. Nearly all these rituals, in this
association or others, have followed the traditional recipe so well summarized
by Shepard Clough. In a systematic
review of our past meetings Shep found that “most of our presidential addresses
have been devoted to making suggestions for research (mostly to be undertaken by
others), to delineating the broad ‘tasks’ of economic history, to defending the
kind of work in which the speaker has been engaged, and to advocating some
particular methodology in our discipline.” Mine is no
exception.
This is a talk about decisions; and let me begin with a
personal one. Mine to become an
economic historian was real enough. There was a genuine alternative. Shortly after Herbert Heaton had
attracted me toward economic history, I was asked to assist in editing the
letters of Theodore Roosevelt. Immersing myself in the selection and
annotation of the correspondence of one of the most active and articulate
American presidents provided me with an inside view of the decision-making
processes in the nation’s most powerful office. The significance of this type of data for
understanding major political, military and diplomatic developments has been
reinforced
1
during the past eight years in editing the vast
correspondence of Dwight D. Eisenhower.
Such work pulled me away from economic history. Roosevelt and Eisenhower were involved in
myriad issues, only a very few of which were of special interest to the
practitioners of our field. But my
earlier interest in economic history was strengthened when I had a chance to
review the papers of two men who were near the heart of the twentieth century
economy, Alfred P. Sloan, Jr. and Pierre S. du Pont. In the case of Sloan of General Motors
fame, I had the opportunity, as I have had with Eisenhower, to talk at length
with a key actor about the decisions he had made and the actions he had
taken.
Such close study of these men, all of whom had a
powerful impact on the organizations in which they worked and on the economies
and polities in which they operated, left three clear impressions. First, this experience emphasized the
value of the documentary record. The documents of these men were more than
mere records. They were the
instruments of action of real men whose choices directly affected the lives of
thousands, indeed hundreds of thousands, of people. The documents indicated the motives as
well as methods of the decision makers far more accurately than views of outside
observers, current or contemporary. Interpretations of why these men spoke
and acted as they did will of course change; but to be convincing, any
interpretations must be based on the documentary record.
A second impression was that the decision makers were
normally faced with extremely complex alternatives. Their choices were limited but choices
had to be made. Moreover, making
these decisions normally involved conflict. It is hard to recall any important
decision in which these four men were involved where there was not genuine
disagreement at the top. Even when
motives were similar, different men often chose different alternatives. An awareness of the alternatives
perceived by the key actors (as well as those they did not see); an awareness of
the information on which choices were based; and an awareness of the process by
which the final choice was determined is essential to an understanding of the
larger issues and events in which these men were involved.
My third point is that, although Roosevelt and
Eisenhower, and du Pont and Sloan, concerned themselves with very different
types of problems, the processes by which decisions were reached and actions
implemented had many similarities. And these
similarities
differentiated their activities and careers from those
of earlier presidents, generals and businessmen. Theirs were usually group decisions,
based on a vast flow of information, and synthesized by offices within the
enterprise. The information that
went up the line as well as the directives that went down, passed through an
extensive bureaucracy which could turn and shape them, and which required a
never-ending process of checks and review. For this reason Sloan’s day to day
activities were closer to Eisenhower’s than they were, say, to those of John
Jacob Astor or even Cornelius Vanderbilt; Eisenhower’s were much closer to
Sloan’s than to those of Andrew Jackson or even Ulysses S.
Grant.
A primary task of historians has always been to record
and analyze the motives of, the alternatives open to, and the actions taken by
men whose decisions have directly affected many people and indirectly helped to
shape the institutions in which the bulk of the population carried on their
daily work. An additional task
awaiting historians who use the documentary record is to look at the process of
decision making itself; to analyze the institutional arrangements within which
the decisions were made; to investigate how and why these processes and
institutions have changed over time; and finally, to consider how such changes
have themselves affected the alternatives and actions open to the decision
makers. For economic history such
analysis provides the central challenge to business and entrepreneurial
historians.
The value of such historical analysis is emphasized when
we consider how drastically the institutions in which economic decisions are
made have been re-shaped during the past century and a half. These changes have not only altered the
process of deciding about prices, investment, output, inventory, employment and
technological and organizational innovation. They have also created new types of
business enterprise and helped to reform the structure of many industries and
indeed the organization of whole economies. In viewing these developments I will
consider only the American scene, for here my information is the fullest. Yet a brief look at the experience of
3
Until the 1850’s, most economic decisions were made in
the
Only a very few businesses were large enough to be
divided into sub-sections. These
few - textile mills, ironworks, and cotton, rice and tobacco plantations - had
only a single manager to supervise the work of a handful of foremen. Decisions concerning the enterprise were
rarely made by more than a couple of men. These units had little systematic
internal organization. Their
accounts were merely records of financial transactions. Their clerical staffs were even smaller
than those of the merchants. Economic enterprise was still wholly a
personal affair. The individuals
and partners who operated these small personal enterprises had little control
over their supplies, markets and prices. Their actions were based on external (not
internally generated) information and such information was rarely fresh or full.
The model of the economy, defined
long ago by classical economists, made some sense in early nineteenth-century
After 1850 a new and very different type of
decision-making unit appeared. It
was a large, multi-unit enterprise operated by managers rather than owners.
It appeared suddenly and almost
full blown in the 1850’s to operate the major railroad and telegraph lines.
Then, similar large enterprises
began to appear in industries and trades, where the use of new technologies
permitted high-volume production and where the new transportation and
communication systems encouraged high volume distribution. The origins and growth of this new style
enterprise involved two processes. One was the internal subdivision of
railroads, factories, and marketing enterprises into smaller sub-units. More important, however, was the
consolidation of already specialized, subdivided units into larger
enterprises.
The centralized coordination, evaluation, and planning
for the activities of a large number of sub-units which often carried out
several different functions of production, distribution, and transportation
within a single, purely private enterprise was something new in economic
history. Such needs brought the
managerial enter-
prise into being. The new enterprises could not run
efficiently without a formal internal organization. They required the generation of internal
operating, financial and cost data. Only through a flow of internal
impersonal statistics could control of these large enterprises be maintained.
Finally they needed the services of
a large number of specially, often technically trained managers. The operating requirements of the new
multi-unit enterprises thus gave rise to a new type of decision-making unit and
to a new class of decision makers.
The appearance of these great administrative networks
altered the external relations between decision-making units and between these
units and the larger environment. In many industries as many transactions
came to be carried on within the enterprise as were carried on between the
company and other enterprises. Prices came to be based more on cost
estimates than on the impersonal forces of supply and demand. The structure of numerous industries and
in fact the structure of entire economies was changed. The concentrated economic power of the
new enterprises stimulated the growth of countervailing institutions in the form
of labor unions and a new role for government in the form of regulatory
commissions.
The sudden appearance and swift spread of large
managerial enterprise was closely related to the increased speed of
transportation, communication, distribution, and production. Increased speed in turn was made possible
by new technologies, particularly those that permitted the exploitation of
energy stored in the fossil fuels. The application of steam and electricity
to transportation and communication permitted a continuous and steady flow of
goods across the land at a speed hitherto impossible to attain. And the new speed demanded
organization.
Canals and turnpikes had required almost no management
at all. In 1840 the managerial
force on the
5
of millions of capital investment. And as early as 1867
The potential of the new means of transportation and
communication could only be fully realized through new methods of organization.
The operation of the railroad and
telegraph systems required the creation of a complex managerial structure to
assure steady and continuing flows of information and orders essential to guide
the movement of trains, traffic, and messages. Because of greater speed and fewer
transshipments, a railroad car could make in two days the round trip that had
required a stage coach or canal boat a week. By careful coordination of flow within
and between the large railroad enterprises, the time involved decreased still
more. As the rate of traffic flow
increased, so did output per worker and per unit of capital and equipment used
in the movement of goods.
The expanded speed of transportation and communications
quickly brought the large scale enterprise into the distribution of goods. In the marketing of agricultural
commodities and manufactured products the factor and the commission merchant
were replaced very quickly by brand new marketing institutions. Large commodity buyers of grain and
cotton began to purchase directly from the producer at the rail head and sell to
the flour miller or the textile factory in this country and abroad, using
futures and “hedging” and handling their transactions through specialized
commodity and produce exchanges that first made their appearance in the 1850’s
and 1860’s. In the same years full
line wholesale jobbers created international buying and regional and often
national selling organizations. The
first great mass retailers - the department stores - appeared in the 1860’s and
1870’s to sell to the concentrated urban markets. Shortly thereafter Montgomery Ward and
Sears Roebuck began to retail to the rural market by mail. Then came the first of the chains in
groceries, drugs, and notions that were to become so predominant in the
twentieth century. All mass
marketers of finished goods - the wholesale jobber, the department store, the
mail order house and the chains - created similar organizations. They had buyers for each major line who
set the prices, specifications, and volume of goods handled, while their
operating organization became responsible for the physical movement of the goods
from the supplier to the consumer. Where the railroad and
telegraph
made possible direct, through-flow of goods without
transshipment from one commercial center to another, the new mass marketers
coordinated flows directly from the individual producer to the individual
consumer.
For the mass marketers velocity or rate of flow was a
basic criterion of performance.
They called it stock turn.
High stock turn permitted high volume of sales with the same plant and
personnel, cut unit costs, and permitted a higher profit at lower margins. And the volume thus attained was
impressive. In 1840 annual sales of
$500,000 were still exceptional for a merchant specializing in the marketing of
manufactured products. In 1873,
seven years after Marshall Field established his wholesale house in
In mass marketing, increased velocity within the firm
came from organization alone. In
large scale production it resulted from the employment of better machines and an
increasing application of energy as well as improved organization. In most mechanical industries, such as
those involved in the production of cloth and lumber, and in the fabrication and
assembling of clothing and of wood and leather products, increases in velocity
were limited by the energies and abilities of men handling the machines. The limits of increased speed of cutting
and shaping wood, cloth, and leather by machinery were quickly reached and
energy could be used only to power these machines.
On the other hand, in the heat using and metal working
industries far greater opportunities existed for increasing velocity of
through-put by improving machinery and by applying energy more intensively.
Again, as in transportation and
distribution, the realization of the potential for increased efficiency required
the creation of an organization to coordinate and control the faster operations
being undertaken. In the refining
industries - petroleum, chemicals, sugar and some other foods - the intensified
use of heat by “cracking” and super-heated steam processes as well as the
improved design of stills and refineries to permit continuous operation,
multistage distillation, greatly enlarged the daily through-put. In the
7
furnace industries - iron, steel and other metals, glass
and rubber - improved furnaces,
converters, rolling and finishing equipment and carefully designed plants vastly
increased the amount of energy consumed by these mills and greatly expanded the
volume of output per man and per unit of capital per day. In both the refining and furnace
industries increased velocity demanded the creation of managerial organizations
to assure a full and steady use of men and equipment.
In metal working, improved management became even more
essential than in the refining and furnace industries to obtaining and
maintaining a high velocity of through-put. Here the basic material required more
time to cut and shape than did cloth, leather, and wood. Finer tolerances were demanded in the
fabrication and assembling of machinery and other metal products than in the
making of clothes or furniture. Thus, the period from the 1850’s to the
1870’s witnessed the major innovations in American machine tools and these
innovations came primarily in machines produced for the metal working
industries. Then, in the 1880’s and
1890’s the major innovations in factory management came in these same
industries. It was here that
systematic or scientific management was developed by Frederick W. Taylor, Henry
R. Towne, and Alexander H. Church in order to get the maximum use from men and
machines. Improved management, in
turn, encouraged the more intensive application of energy.
These became the mass production industries in the
modern sense. In all - in oil,
sugar and other refined products; in iron, steel and other metals, glass,
rubber, chemicals; in complex machinery, particularly electrical, and then the
automobile - plant and equipment replaced men. These industries became capital
intensive. The need to keep this
capital employed by maintaining a continuing high rate of through-put caused
such enterprises to move backward to obtain a more certain supply of raw and
semi-finished materials and to move forward to assure direct and regular
deliv-
In textiles, lumber, leather, clothing, shoes,
furniture, printing and publishing, and many foods, the opportunities for
increasing the velocity of through-put by an intensified application of energy
and by improved systems of management remained limited. In those industries therefore,
enterprises stayed small, non-integrated and labor intensive. In them, large firms had few cost and
productivity advantages over small ones. Those industries remained competitive,
although the enterprises in them relied increasingly on the mass marketers to
sell their products.
This briefest of historical sketches of the rise of
large scale managerial enterprise in American transportation, communications,
distribution, and production, emphasizes that the economies of scale within the
firm resulted far more from speed than from size. It was not the size of an enterprise but
the velocity of through-put that permitted economies that lowered costs and
increased output per worker and per machine and so provided the classic,
competitive advantage. The savings
from using the same power, light, maintenance and other facilities were small
compared to those made by greatly increasing the daily use of equipment and
personnel. Speed brought size; but
size in no sense insured speed.
For example, improvements in the design of petroleum
refineries and stills permitted a 6,500 barrel daily through-put by the
mid-1880’s as compared to a 1,000 barrel one a few years before. The new, large refineries brought the
cost down from 50 to 1/20 a barrel. Quickly, close to two-fifths of the
petroleum processed in the
Economies of speed came, then, in production when
manufacturing processes permitted an increased application of energy just as
they came in transportation, communications, and distribution with the
application of steam and electricity. In all cases, however, organization
provided by the large managerial enterprise became neces-
9
sary to develop fully and to maintain economies of
speed. And unless such organization
was achieved, large corporations had difficulty in remaining viable business
units over an extended period of time.
Once such economies were attained, the large managerial,
multi-unit enterprise rarely disappeared. At least it continued on until its
product or function became technologically obsolete. It might be merged into another
enterprise or its resources might be transferred into another line of business,
but the men, money and materials once accumulated were rarely dissipated. Unlike the entrepreneur and his partners,
the new managerial enterprise did not retire, die, or even fade away. It came to have a life of its
own.
The need to keep accumulated resources fully employed
created stronger internal pressures to achieve steady growth than existed in the
small personal enterprise. The new
marketing enterprises grew by adding lines, enlarging purchasing organizations,
and expanding operating units through the building of branches and chains. Mass production enterprises at first
continued to grow by integration. The search for markets quickly took them
abroad to the advanced economies of
Small personal enterprise, it must be stressed, did not
disappear. It still peoples
agriculture and other industries in the biologically oriented primary sector of
the economy as well as most of the construction industries, and some of the
industries in the service or tertiary sector. It is often found in the forefront of
technological innovation. Yet even
in these sectors the managerial enterprise has gained rapidly since World War
II. The small retailer, for
example, has been replaced by the mass marketer in many trades, and chains have
moved into many services such as hotels, road-side eating and car
rentals.
In the
secondary sector the size and numbers of
managerial
enterprises expanded impressively all through the
twentieth century. The tremendous
increase in the use of electricity, petroleum, and natural gas greatly expanded
the exploitation of the energy provided by fossil fuels. The replacement of biologically produced
materials like cloth, wood, and leather by chemically produced synthetics made
possible further increases in the velocity of production. So too did the application of
electronics, especially through automation and the computer. Increased velocity in turn intensified
the need for complex managerial organization. The resulting economies of speed must
surely help to explain why what economists term “the residual” has become large
by the mid-twentieth century.
The replacement of small personal enterprises by large
managerial ones in many industries radically altered the nature of the
decision-making unit, the process of decision making and the types of decisions
made within the unit. This
transition also altered the recruitment, training, and even the goals of the
decision makers themselves. Buying
and selling, carried out on a far greater scale than had been done by any
earlier business enterprise, was now handled by specialists for whom price was
usually only one of several specifications. Other specialized managers concentrated
on scheduling and coordinating the flow of goods through their departments or
through the enterprise as a whole. A number of others spent their full time
on the development of new products and processes, while still others came to
concentrate on relations with the working force, stockholders, governmental
offices, and the public.
The senior executives at the top attempted to focus
their energies on the critical decisions concerning present and future
allocation of resources. Such
investment decisions involved amounts far exceeding those made by the earlier
personal enterprises and included the allocation of skilled and specially
trained personnel as well as funds. Such long-term investment decisions came
to be made by groups. At first,
when the enterprise was new, representatives of investors or the founders and
their families conferred with the managers. Within a generation, however, the
full-time executives had taken over the major investment and policy formulating
decisions. Only they had the
necessary information and knowledge. The Board of Directors could no longer
direct - it had become little more than a ratifying body.
The experience and outlook of the new managerial
decision makers was very different from that of the older entrepreneurs
and
11
partners. They had little financial interest in the
enterprises they operated, and if the managers did not own, neither did the
owners manage. These managers
usually attended college, acquiring specialized training in engineering and then
in business management. Indeed, the
rise of American engineering and business schools was a direct response to the
demands of the new, large enterprises for managers. The latter quickly formed professional
societies where they met regularly to discuss mutual problems and activities.
They looked on their work within
the enterprises as a lifetime career to be spent climbing up the executive
ladder with the expectation of retirement at 65 on a pension. Until the age of 50 these managers
remained specialists, concentrating in internal tasks, almost none of which had
existed before the coming of the railroads.
It is difficult to conceive of a greater difference
between the roles, training, experience, and activities of the decision makers
who manage the high velocity of through-put in the mid-twentieth century economy
and those of the men who carried on the smaller and much slower economic
activities of early nineteenth-century
The importance of this illustration is not only that the
managerial class in 1840 was tiny, but also that these men were usually the only
managers in their enterprises. Except for a miniscule number
of
12
plantation stewards, almost none of these managers
managed other managers. There was
no middle or top management in 1840. In that day managers worked closely with
the owners. Their enterprises
remained personal ones.
On the other hand, there are today approximately 10,000
managers in the du Pont Company above the level of first line supervisor. These are all linked together in a single
administrative network. Literally
hundreds of managers at du Pont manage other managers, carrying out tasks that
did not exist in 1840. But they
rarely confer with the owners or their representatives. Theirs is purely a managerial
enterprise.
And du Pont is only one of many hundreds of comparable
enterprises. One has only to look
out on
The managers in these general offices are surely the
most important set of economic decision makers in the
13
The same is true in other industrial and technologically
advanced economies. Despite a
stronger commitment to government supervision - to a belief in a mixed economy -
the decisions in nearly all the high technology and growth industries in
That fundamental changes have occurred since 1850 in the
process of economic decision making, in the institutions which make decisions,
and in the type of men who make them, seems obvious. Few would seriously argue that major
economic decisions in industrialized, technologically advanced countries - those
that have achieved sustained economic growth - are still made by individuals and
partners rather than by career managers operating within large enterprises.
Nor would anyone claim that the
institutions through which modern economies are managed have remained unchanged.
Yet some historians and economists
still deal with the economic developments of the past 150 years as if the
decision-making process and the resulting management of production,
distribution, transportation, communications, and finance have remained much the
same since 1850. Since this is the
case; since the transformation has been relatively recent; and since the
awareness of the new style of making decisions and of the institutions through
which they are made and carried out is so essential to an understanding of the
operation and control of modern economies; since all this is so, historical
analysis of the transition from the personal to the managerial enterprise and
the resulting impact on the economic order is surely a vital field of
study.
Let me, then, conclude this traditional presentation of
a time-honored ritual by urging economic historians to look further into the
rise, spread, and impact of managerial enterprise, not only in this country, but
abroad. It is a field that should
have a special appeal to historians who find satisfaction in working with the
documentary record. Admittedly the
focus is narrow. It deals only with
a period of a couple of hundred years and it addresses itself only to one aspect
or thread of economic history. Yet its very narrowness
14
opens the way for careful comparative analysis and
interdisciplinary work that would be far more difficult in carrying out a
broader, less well defined problem. Analyses of the rise of a new and most
powerful economic class, of a new and most formidable economic institution is
still a large order. The dominance
of our society by this and other large-scale organizations is one characteristic
of the twentieth century that distinguishes it from all others. The enormously increased speed and volume
of economic activity is another. An
analysis of the creation and growth of managerial enterprise and of the new
managerial class can tell us much about the why and the how of recent economic
change. It can provide us, I think,
with new insights into the distinctive nature of the modem
world.
ALFRED D. CHANDLER, JR.,
15