The Competitiveness of Nations in a Global Knowledge-Based Economy
Fred Block *
“Introduction”to
The Great Transformation
by Karl
Polanvi
Beacon
Press, 2001
* Department of Sociology
University of California, Davis
Content
Polanyi’s
Argument: Structure and Theory
Polanyi's
Concept of Embeddedness
Why Disembedding Cannot be Successful
The Consequences of Impossibility
The Centrality of the Global Regime |
Introduction
[i]
An
eminent economic historian, reviewing the reception and influence of The
Great Transformation, remarked that “Some books refuse to go away.” It is an apt statement. Although written in the early 1940’s, the relevance
and importance of Polanyi’s work has continued to
grow. While few books these days have a
shelf life of more than a few months or a few years, after many decades, The
Great Transformation remains fresh. Indeed,
it is indispensable for understanding the dilemmas facing global society at the
beginning of the twenty-first century.
There
is a good explanation for this durability. The Great Transformation provides the
most powerful critique yet produced of market liberalism - the belief that both
national societies and the global economy can and should be organized through
self-regulating markets. Since the
1980s, and particularly with the end of the Cold War in the early 199’s, this
doctrine of market liberalism, under the labels of “Thatcherism,” “Reaganism,” “Neoliberalism,” and
“the Washington Consensus,”has come to dominate
global politics. But shortly after it
was
i - I have incurred significant debts in preparing this
introduction. The greatest is to Kari Polanyi Levitt who provided
extensive and detailed comments, both substantive and editorial, on several
different drafts. It has been a rare
privilege to work with her. Michael Flota, Miriam Joffe-Block,
Marguerite Mendell, and Margaret Somers also gave me
valuable feedback. Margaret Somers has
been helping me to understand Polanyi’s thought for
close to thirty years; much of what I have written reflects her thinking. In addition, Michael Flota
provided assistance in the preparation of the introduction and in the larger
task of preparing this new edition.
I also have a considerable debt to Kari Polanyi
Levitt and Marguerite Mendell
in their roles as the co-directors of the Karl Polanyi
Institute of Political Economy (located at Concordia University, Montreal,
Quebec). My understanding of Polanyi’s thought has been deeply shaped by their
colleagueship and by the archive of Polanyi’s papers
that they maintain. Readers who want to
learn more about Karl Polanyi’s thought and the
international community of scholars working in this tradition should contact
the Karl Polanyi Institute and consult the important
series of books, Critical Perspectives on Historic Issues, that the Institute has published
with Black Rose Press in Montreal.
first
published in 1944, the Cold War between the United States and the Soviet Union
intensified, obscuring the importance of Polanyi’s
contribution. In the highly polarized
debates between the defenders of capitalism and the defenders of Soviet-style
socialism, there was little room for Polanyi’s
nuanced and complex arguments. Hence,
there is a certain justice that with the ending of the Cold War era, Polanyi’s work is beginning to gain the visibility it
deserves.
The
core debate of this post-Cold War period has been over “globalization.” Neoliberals have
insisted that the new technologies of communications and transportation make it
both inevitable and desirable that the world economy be tightly integrated
through expanded trade and capital flows and the acceptance of the Anglo-American
model of free market capitalism. A wide
variety of movements and theorists around the world have attacked this vision
of globalization from different political perspectives - some resisting on the
basis of ethnic, religious, national, or regional identities, and others
upholding alternative visions of global coordination and cooperation. Those on both sides of this debate have much
to learn from reading The Great Transformation; both neoliberals
and their critics will obtain a deeper grasp of the history of market
liberalism and an understanding of the tragic consequences of earlier projects
of economic globalization.
Karl
Polaniyi (1996-1964) was raised in Budapest, in a
family remarkable for its social engagement arid intellectual achievements. [ii] His brother, Michael
became an important philosopher of science whose work is still
ii - There is not yet a full biography of Polanyi, but much of the relevant material is covered in Marguerite
Mendell and Kari Levitt Polanyi, “Karl Polanyi - His Life
and Times” Studies in Political Economy. No. 22 (Spring 1997): 7-39. See also, Kari Polanyi
Levitt, ed., Life and Work of Karl Polanyi and her essay, “Karl Polanyi
as Socialist,’ in Kenneth McRobbie, ed., Humanity,
Society and Commitment: On Karl Polanyi. (Montreal: Black Rose, 1994). Extensive biographical material is also
available in Kenneth McRobbie and Kari Polanyi Levitt, eds., Karl Polanyi in Vienna. Montreal: Black Rose, 2000. Peter Dmcker, the management
theorist who knew the Polanyi family in Vienna, has written
an amusing account in his memoir, Adventures of a Bystander, New York: [John Wiley, 1994), but many of the specific facts
including some of the names of Polanyi’s siblings -
are inaccurate.]
HHC: [bracketed] displayed on page 3 of original
2
widely
read. Karl himself had been an
influential personality in Hungarian student arid intellectual circles before
World War I.
In
Vienna, in the 1920’s, Karl worked as senior editor for the premier economic
and financial weekly of Central Europe, Der
Oesterreichishe Volkswirt.
It was during this time that he first
encountered the arguments of Ludwig von Mises and his
more famous student, Frierich Hayek. Mises and Hayek were
attempting to restore the intellectual legitimacy of market liberalism which
had been badly shaken by the First World War, the Russian Revolution, arid the
appeal of socialism. [iii] In
the short term, Mises and Hayek had little influence.
From the mid 1930s through the 1960s, Keynesian
economic ideas legitimating active government management of economies dominated
national policies in the West. [iv] But throughout the decades following
the second World War, Mises and Hayek were tireless
proponents for market liberalism in the U.S. and the U.K., and they directly
inspired such influential followers as Milton Friedman. Hayek lived until 1992, long enough to feel
vindicated by the collapse of the Soviet Union. By the time of his death, he was widely
celebrated as the father of neoliberalism - the
person who had inspired both Margaret Thatcher and Ronald Reagan to pursue
policies of deregulation, liberalization, arid privatization. As early as the 1920’s, however, Polanyi directly challenged von Mises’s
arguments and the critique
iii - For an account of Mises
and Hayek from the 1920’s through the 1990’s, see Richard Cockett,
Thinking the Unthinkable: Think Tanks and the Economic Counter-Revolution
1931-1993. London: Fontana Press, 1995. Cockett stresses the
irony that England that invented market liberalism had to reimport
it from Vienna.
iv - By coincidence, Polanyi's
book was first published in the same year that Hayek published his most famous
book, The Road to Serfdom (Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1944). While the former celebrated the
New Deal in the United States precisely because it placed limits on the
influence of market forces, the latter book insisted that the New Deal reforms
placed the United States on a slippery slope that would lead both to economic
ruin and a totalitarian regime.
of
the market liberals continued as his central theoretical concern.
During
his tenure at Der Oesterreichische
Volkswirt, Polanyi
witnessed the U.S. stock market crash 1929, the failure of the Vienna Kreditaristalt in 1931, which precipitated the Great
Depression, and the rise of fascism. But
with Hitler’s ascent to power in 1933, Polanyi’s socialist
views became problematic, and he was asked to resign his position. He left for England where he worked as a
lecturer for the Workers Educational Association, the extra-mural outreach arm
of the Universities of Oxford and London. [v] Developing his courses
led Polanyi to immerse himself in the materials of English
social and economic history. In The
Great Transformation, Polanyi fused these
historical materials to his critique of von Mises and
Hayek’s now extraordinarily influential views.
The
actual writing was done while Polanyi was a visiting
scholar at Bennington College in Vermont in the early 1940s. [vi] With the support of a
fellowship, he could devote full time to writing. And the change of perspective helped Polanyi synthesize the different strands of his argument. One of the book’s enduring contributions - its
focus on the institutions that regulate the global economy - was directly linked
to Polanyi’s multiple exiles. His moves from Budapest to Vienna to England and
then to the United States, combined with a deep sense of moral responsibility,
made Polanyi a kind of world citizen. Towards the end of his life he wrote to an old
friend: “My life was a ‘world’ life - I lived the life of the human world. My work is for Asia, for Africa, for the new
peoples.” [vii]
While
he retained a deep attachment to his native Hungary, his “world” life helped him
to transcend a Eurocentric view and to grasp the ways that aggressive forms of
nationalism had been fostered and supported by a certain set of global economic
arrangements.
In
the years after W.W. II, Polanyi taught at Columbia
University in New York City, where he and his
v - Marguerite Mendell, “Karl Polariyi and
Socialist Education,” pp.25-42 in McRobbie, ed., Humanity,
Society and Commitment.
vii - Polariyi wrote the book in
English; he had been fluent in English since childhood.
viii - Letter to Be de Waard, January 6, 1959, cited on p.313 by Ilona Duczynska Polanyi, “I First Met Karl Polanyi
in 1920...,” pp.302-315 in McRobbie arid Levitt, eds., Karl Polanyi inVienna.
4
students
engaged in anthropological research on money, trade and markets in pre
-capitalist societies. With Conrad Arensberg and Harry Pearson, he published Trade and
Markets in the Early Empires (New York: Free Press, 1957); later, his
student prepared for publication posthumous volumes based on his work of this
period. Abraham Rotstein
assisted with the publication of Dahomey
and the Slave Trade (Seattle: University of Washington, 1966), George
Dalton edited a collection of previously published essays, including excerpts
from The Great Transformation, in Primitive, Archaic and Modern
Economies: Essays of Karl Polanyi (Boston:
Beacon, 1971 [1969]), and Harry Pearson compiled The Livelihood of Man (New
York: Academic Press, 1977) from Polanyi’s Columbia
lecture notes.
Polanyi’s
Argument: Structure and Theory
The Great Transformation is organized into three parts. Parts I and III focus on the immediate circumstances that produced the first World War, the Great Depression, the rise of fascism in Continental Europe, the New Deal in the United States, and the first five year plan in the Soviet Union. In these introductory and concluding chapters, Polanyi sets up a puzzle: Why did a prolonged period of relative peace and prosperity in Europe, lasting from 1815 to 1914, suddenly gave way to economic collapse and the savagery of two World Wars. Part II - the core of the book - provides Polanyi’s solution to the puzzle. Going back to the English Industrial Revolution, in the first years of the 19th Century, Polanyi shows how English thinkers responded to the disruptions of early industrialization by developing the theory of market liberalism, with its core belief that human society should be subordinated to self-regulating markets. As a result of England’s leading role as “workshop of the world,” he explains these beliefs became the organizing principle for the world economy. In the second half of Part II, chapters 11 through 19, Polanyi argues that market liberalism produced an inevitable response - concerted efforts to protect society from the market. These efforts meant that market liberalism could not work as intended, and the institutions governing the global economy created increasing tensions within and between nations. The collapse of peace that led to World War I, and the collapse of economic order leading to the Great Depression, are shown to be the direct consequence of attempting to organize the global economy on the basis of market liberalism. The second “great transformation - the rise of
fascism
- is a result of the first “great transformation” - the rise of market liberalism.
In
making his argument, Polanyi draws on his deep
reading of history, anthropology, and social theory. [viii]
The Great Transformation
has important things to say on historical events from the 15th Century to World
War II; it also makes original contributions on topics as diverse as the role
of reciprocity and redistribution in pre -modern societies, the limitations of classical
economic thought, and the dangers of commodifying
nature. Many contemporary social
scientists - anthropologists, political scientists, sociologists, historians,
and economists - have found theoretical inspiration from Polanyi’s
arguments and today a growing number of books and articles are framed around key
quotations from The Great Transformation.
The
very richness of this book means that it is futile to try to summarize it; the
best that can be done is to elaborate some of the main strands of Polanyi’s argument. But
doing this requires first recognizing the originality of his theoretical
position. Polanyi
does not fit easily into our standard mappings of the political landscape;
while he agreed with much of Keynes’ critique of market liberalism, he was
hardly a Keynesian. He identified
throughout his life as a socialist, but he had profound differences with
economic determinism of all varieties, including mainstream Marxism. [ix] His very definition of
capitalism and socialism diverges from our customary understandings of those
concepts.
viii - For an analysis
of some of Polanyi’s key sources, see Margaret
Somers, “Karl Polanyi’s Intellectual Legacy,” pp.
152-1 59 in Levitt, ed., Life and Work of Karl Polanyi.
ix - Polanyi’s relationship to
Marxism is one of the most complex and debated issues in the literature. See Mendell and Levitt Polanyi, “Karl Polanyi - His Life arid Times”; Fred Block and Margaret
Somers, “Beyond the Economistic Fallacy: The Holistic
Social Science of Karl Polanyi,” pp. 47-94 in Theda Skocpol, ed., Vision and
Method in Historical Sociology, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
1994); Rhoth H. Haper in, Cultural
Economies: Past and Present (Austin: University of Texas Press, 1994.
6
Polanyi's
Concept of Embeddedness
The
logical starting point for explaining Polanyi’s thinking
is his concept of embeddedness. Perhaps his most famous contribution to social
thought, it has also been a source of enormous
confusion in understanding his argument. Polanyi starts by
emphasizing that the entire tradition of modern economic thought, continuing up
to the present moment, rests on the conception of the economy as an
interlocking system of markets that automatically adjust supply and demand
through the price mechanism. Even when
economists acknowledge that the market system sometimes need help from
government to overcome market failure, they still rely on this
conceptualization of the economy as an equilibrating system of integrated
markets. Polanyi’s
intent is to show how sharply this conceptualization differs from the reality
of human societies throughout recorded human histomy.
Prior to the nineteenth century, he
insists, the human economy was always embedded in society.
The
term “embeddedness” expresses the idea that the
economy is not autonomous as it must be in economic theory, but subordinated to
politics, religion, arid social relations. [x] Polanyi’s
use of the term suggests more than the now familiar idea that market
transactions depend on trust, mutual understanding, and legal enforcement of contracts.
He uses the concept to highlight how
radical a break the classical economists, especially Malthus
and Ricardo, made with previous thinkers. Instead of the historically normal pattern of
subordinating the economy to society, their system of self-regulating markets
required subordinating society to the logic of the market:
x - Polanyi’s
concept of embeddedness has been borrowed and
elaborated on by important contemporary scholars including John Ruggie, “International Regimes, Transactions, and Change:
Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order, International Organization
362 (Spring 1992):379-415, Mark Grariovetter,
“Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness,
American Journal of Sociology 91:3 November 1995): 491-510, and Peter Evaris, Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation.
(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1995) The precise inspiration for the coinage is not
known, but it seems plausible that Polanyi drew the
metaphor from coalmining. In researching
English economic history, he read extensively on the history and technologies
of the English mining industry that faced the task of extracting coal that was
embedded in the rock walls of the mine.
“Ultimately that is why the control of the economic system by the
market is of overwhelming consequence to the whole organization of society: it
means no less than the running of society as an adjunct to the market. Instead of economy being embedded in social
relations, social relations are embedded in the economic system.” (57)
Yet this and similar
passages lend themselves to a misreading of Polanyi’s
argument. Polanyi
is often understood to be saying that with the rise of capitalism in the
nineteenth century, the economy was successfully disembedded
from society and came to dominate it. [xi]
This misreading, however, obscures the originality and theoretical richness of Polariyi’s argument. Polanyi does say that the classical economists wanted to create a society in which the economy had been effectively disembedded and they encouraged politicians to pursue this objective. Yet Polanyi also insists that they did not and could not achieve this goal. In fact, he repeatedly says that the goal of a fully self-regulating market economy that is disembedded is a utopian project; it is something that cannot exist. On the opening page of the book, he writes:
“Our thesis is that the idea of a self-adjusting market implied a stark
utopia. Such an institution could not
exist for any length of time without annihilating the human and natural
substance of society; it would have physically destroyed man and transformed
his surroundings into a wilderness. (3)
Why Disembedding
Cannot be Successful
Polanyi argues that creating a fully self-regulating market
economy requires that human beings and the natural environment be turned into
pure commodities and this assures the destruction of both society and the
natural environment. In his view, the
theorists of self-regulating markets and their allies are constantly pushing
human
xi - No less a figure than the great French historian, Fernand Braudel, reads Polanyi in this way. See Civilization and Capitalism 15th-19th
Century, vol.2, The Wheels of Commerce, tr. by Sian
Reynolds (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992), pp.225-229.
8
societies
to the edge of a precipice. But as the consequences
of unrestrained markets become apparent, people resist; they refuse to act like
lemmings marching over a cliff to their own destruction. Instead, they retreat from the tenets of market
self-regulation in order to save society and nature from destruction. In this sense, one might say that disembedding the market is similar to stretching a giant
elastic band. Efforts to bring about
greater autonomy of the market increase the level of tension. With further stretching, either the band will
snap - representing social disintegration - or the economy will revert to a
more embedded position.
The
logic underlying this argument rests on Polanyi’s
distinction between real and fictitious commodities. For Polanyi, the
definition of a commodity is something that has been produced for sale on a
market. By this definition, land, labor,
and money are fictitious commodities because they were not originally produced
to be sold on a market. Labor is simply the
activity of human beings, land is subdivided nature, and the supply of money
and credit in modern societies is necessarily shaped by governmental policies. Modern economics starts by pretending that
these fictitious commodities will behave in the same way as real commodities,
but Polanyi insists that this sleight of hand has
fatal consequences. It means that
economic theorizing is based on a lie and this lie places human society at
risk.
There
are two levels to Polanyi’s argument here. The first is a moral argument that it is
simply wrong to treat nature and human beings as objects whose price will be
determined entirely by the market. Such
a concept violates the principles that have governed societies for centuries:
nature and human life have almost always been recognized as having a sacred
dimension. It is impossible to reconcile
this sacred dimension with the subordination of labor and nature to the market.
In his objection to the treatment of
nature as a commodity, Polanyi anticipates many of the
arguments of contemporary environmentalists. [xii]
The
second level of Polanyi’s argument centers on the
role of the state in the economy. [xiii] Even though the
[xii] For an indication
of his influence on environmental economics, see Hennan
E. Daly and John B. Cobb, Jr., For the Common Good: Redirecting the Economy Toward Community, the Environment, and a Sustainable Future.
(Boston: Beacon Press, 1999).
[xiii]
Implicit in Polanyi’s argument is a more specific
critique of the market as a self-regulating mechanism. In the [case of manufactured
commodities, a falling price for an abundant commodity restores equilibrium by
both encouraging increased consumption and by discouraging new production. In the case of fictitious commodities, the
effectiveness of the price mechanism is reduced because automatic increases or
decreases in supply cannot be assumed.]
HHC: [bracketed] displayed on page 10 of original
economy
is supposed to be self-regulating, the state must play the ongoing role of
adjusting the supply of money and credit to avoid the twin dangers of inflation
and deflation. Similarly, the state has
to manage shifting demand for employees by providing relief in periods of
unemployment, by educating and training future workers, and by seeking to
influence migration flows. In the case
of land, governments have sought to maintain continuity in food production by a
variety of devices that insulate farmers from the pressures of fluctuating
harvests and volatile prices. In urban
areas, governments manage the use of the existing land through both
environmental and land use regulations. In
short, the role of managing fictitious commodities places the state inside
three of the most important markets; it becomes utterly impossible to sustain
market liberalism’s view that the state is “outside” of the economy. [xiv]
The
fictitious commodities explain the impossibility of disembedding
the economy. Real market societies need
the state to play an active role in managing markets, and that role requires
political decision making; it cannot be reduced to some kind of technical or
administrative function. [xv] When
state policies move in the direction of
[xiv] For many other
commodities as well, government involvement is a precondition for market
competition. See the aptly titled book
by Steven Vogel, Freer Markets, More Rules:
Regulatory Reform in Advanced Industrial Countries (Ithaca: Cornell
University Press, 1996).
[xv] Monetarists have
tried repeatedly without success to establish a fixed rule for managing the growth
of the money supply that would eliminate the discretion of central bankers. In the absence of such a formula, the next
recourse is to obscure the political role of central bankers by attributing to
them quasi-religious and oracular authority. See William Greider,
Secrets of the Temple: How the Federal Reserve Runs the Country. New
York: Simon and Schuster, 1997).
10
disembedding through placing greater reliance on
market self-regulation, ordinary people are forced to bear higher costs. Workers and their families are made more vulnerable
to unemployment, farmers are exposed to greater competition from imports, and both
groups are required to get by with reduced entitlements to assistance. It often takes greater state efforts to assure
that these groups will bear these increased costs without engaging in
disruptive political actions. This is
part of what Polanyi means by his claim that
“Laissez-faire was planned....” (141); it requires statecraft and repression to
impose the logic of the market and its attendant risks on ordinary people. [xvi]
The Consequences of Impossibility
Free
market theorists seek to disembed the economy from
society thought; their efforts must eventually fail. But the very utopianism of market liberalism
is a source of its extraordinary intellectual resilience. Since societies invariably draw back from the brink
of full scale experimentation with market self-regulation, its theorists can
always claim that any failures were not the result of the design but of a lack
of political will in its implementation. The creed of market self-regulation thus can’t
be discredited by historical experiences; its advocates have an airtight excuse
for its failures. This has occurred most
recently in the effort to impose market capitalism on the former Soviet Union
through “shock therapy.” While the
failure of this effort is obvious for all to see, defenders of “shock
[xvi] This is Polanyi’s central point in his account of the New Poor Law
in England; the creation of a labor market required a dramatic increase in the
state’s repressive powers. On this
point, Polanyi’s interpretation has been supported by
later scholars, especially Karel Williams, From
Pauperism to Poverty (London: Routledge, 1991). On Speerthamland, a
number of Polanyi’s arguments have been called into
question. Two important but conflicting
accounts of the Old Poor Law are provided in K.D.M. Snell, Annals of the Labouring Poor: Social Change and Agrarian England,
1660-1900 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1995), and George Boyer, An Economic History of the English Poor Law,
1750-1950. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990).
therapy” continue to blame
the failure on politicians who caved too quickly to political pressures; had
they only persisted, the promised benefits of a rapid shift to the market would
haw been realized.’”
Polanyi’s extreme skepticism about disembedding
the economy is also the source of his powerful argument about the “double
movement.” Since efforts to disembed the economy from society inevitably encounter
resistance, Polanyi argues that market societies are
constituted by two opposing movements - the laissez-faire movement to expand
the scope of the market and the protective countermovement that emerges to
resist the disembedding of the economy. While the working class movement has been a key
part of the protective countermovement, Polariyi
explicitly states that all groups in society have participated in this project.
When periodic economic downturns
destroyed the banking system, for example, business groups insisted that
central banking be strengthened to insulate the domestic supply of credit from
the pressures of the global market. [xviii] In a word, even
capitalists periodically resist the uncertainty and fluctuations that market
self-regulation produces and participate in efforts to increase stability arid
predictability through forms of protection.
Polanyi is insistent that “Laissez-faire was planned; planning
was not.” (141) Polariyi
explicitly attacks market liberals who blamed a “collectivist conspiracy” for
erecting protective barriers against the working of global markets. He argues, instead, that this creation of barriers
was a spontaneous and unplanned response by all groups in society against the
impossible pressures of a self-regulating market system. The protective countermovement had to happen
to prevent the disaster of a disembedded economy.
Polanyi suggests that movement towards a laissez-faire
economy needs the countermovement to create
[xvii] For explicitly Polanyian discussions of the transition in Eastern Europe
and the former Soviet Union, see Maurice Glasman, Unnecessary
Suffering : Managing Markets Utopia (London: Verso, 1996, John Gray, False Dawn:
the Delusions of Global Capitalism (London: Granta
Books, 1999), and David Woodruff, Money Unmade: Barter and the Fate of Russian
Capitalism. (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1999).
[xviii] “Modern central
banking, in effect, was essentially a device developed for the purpose of
offering protection without which the market would have destroyed its own
children, the business enterprises of all kinds.” (192)
12
stability.
When, for example, the movement for
laissez-faire is too powerful, as in the 1920s (or the 1990s) in the U.S.,
speculative excesses and growing inequality destroyed the foundations for
continuing prosperity. And while Polanyi’s sympathies are generally with the protective
countermovement, he also recognizes that it can sometimes create a dangerous
political-economic stalemate. His
analysis of the rise of fascism in Europe acknowledges that when neither
movement was able to impose its solution to the crisis, tensions increased
until fascism gained the strength to seize power and break with both
laissez-faire and democracy. [xix]
Polanyi’s thesis of the double movement contrasts strongly
with both market Liberalism and orthodox Marxism in
the range of possibilities that are imagined at any particular moment. Both market liberalism and Marxism argue that
societies have only two real choices; there can be market capitalism or
socialism. While they have opposing
preferences, the two positions agree in excluding any other alternatives. Polanyi, in
contrast, insists that free market capitalism is not a real choice; it is only
a utopian vision. Moreover, he defines
socialism as “the tendency inherent in an industrial civilization to transcend
the self-regulating market by consciously subordinating it to a democratic
society.” (234) This
definition allows for a continuing role for markets within socialist societies.
Polanyi
suggests that there are different possibilities available at any historical
moment, since markets can be embedded in many different ways. To be sure, some of these forms will be more
efficient in their ability to expand output and foster innovation, arid some
will be more “socialist” in subordinating the market to democratic direction,
but Polanyi implies that alternatives that are both
efficient arid democratic were available both in the nineteenth century and the
twentieth. [xx]
[xix] Polanyi addresses fascism in “The Essence of Fascism”
pp.359-394 in J. Lewis, K. Polanyi, and D.K. Kitchin, eds,
Christianity and the Social Revolution.
(London: Gollancz, 1935).
[xx] Polanyi has directly inspired a school of thought that has
flowered in the 1980’s and 1990’s that has analyzed the “varieties of
capitalism” - showing the very significant differences in the ways that markets
are embedded in the U.S. as compared to France, Germany, Japan and other
nations. See Rogers Hollingsworth arid
Robert Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism: the Embeddedness
of Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997, and Cohn
Crouch and Wolfgang Streeck, Political Economy of
Modern Capitalism: Mapping Convergence and [Diversity
(Thousand Oaks, Ca.: Sage, 1997).]
HHC: [bracketed] displayed on page 14 of original
The Centrality of the Global
Regime
Yet Polanyi is far too sophisticated a thinker to imagine that
individual countries are free to choose the particular way in which they want
to reconcile the two sides of the double movement. On the contrary, Polanyi’s
argument is relevant to our current situation precisely because he places the
rules governing the global economy at the center of his framework. His argument about the rise of fascism in the
interwar period pivots on the role of the international gold standard in
constraining the political options that were available to actors within
countries.
To
understand this part of Polanyi’s argument requires a
brief excursion into the logic of the gold standard, but this excursion is
hardly a digression, since the logic of free and autonomous international
capital movement continues to exert a powerful influence on contemporary market
Liberals. Polanyi
saw the gold standard as an extraordinary intellectual achievement; [xxi] it was an institutional innovation that
put the theory of self-regulating markets into practice, and once in place, it
had the power to make self-regulating markets appear to be natural.
Market
Liberals wanted to create a world with maximal opportunities to extend the
scope of markets internationally, but they had to find a way that people in
different countries with different currencies could freely engage in
transactions with each other. They
reasoned that if every country conformed to three simple rules, the global
economy would have the perfect mechanism for global self-regulation. First, each country would set the value of its
currency in relation to a fixed amount of gold and would commit to buying arid
selling gold at that price. Second, each
country would base its domestic money supply on the quantity of gold that it
held in its reserves; its circulating currency would be backed by gold. Third, each country would endeavor to give its
residents maximal freedom to engage in international economic transactions.
[xxi] The idea was
first elaborated by Isaac Gervaise and David Hume in
the 19th Century. Frank Fetter, Development
of British Monetary Orthodoxy 1797-1975. (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard
University Press, 1965), p. 4.
14
The
gold standard put a fantastic machinery of global self-regulation into place. Firms in England were able to export goods and
invest in all parts of the world, confident that the currencies they earned would
be as “good as gold”. In theory, if a
country is in a deficit position in a given year because its citizens spent
more abroad than they earned, gold flows out of that country’s reserves to
clear payments due to foreigners. [xxii] The domestic supply of money
and credit automatically shrinks, interest rates rise, prices and wages fall,
demand for imports declines, and exports become more competitive. The country’s deficit would therefore be
self-liquidating. Without the heavy hand
of government, each nation’s international accounts would reach a balance. The globe would be unified into a single
market place without the need for some kind of world government or global
financial authority; sovereignty would remain divided among many nation-states
whose self-interest would lead them to adopt the gold standard rules
voluntarily.
Consequences of the Gold Standard
The
gold standard was intended to create an integrated global marketplace that
reduced the role of national units and national governments, but its
consequences were exactly the opposite. [xxiii] Polanyi
shows that when it was widely adopted in the 1870’s, it had the ironic effect
of intensifying the importance of the nation as a unified entity. While market liberals dreamed of a pacified world
in which the only international struggles would be those of individuals and
firms to outperform their competitors, their efforts to realize these dreams
through the gold standard
[xxii] The mechanism by
which the gold would flow out is equally ingenious and requires no governmental
action. Since people in the deficit
nation are spending more abroad than they are taking in, their currency - being
in greater supply - will fall in value relative to other currencies. When that value falls below a certain level
called the gold point, it will be profitable for international bankers to trade
that currency for gold and ship the gold abroad where it will bring a higher
price. In this way, gold will move from
deficit countries to surplus countries.
[xxiii] As Polanyi knew, the operation of the gold standard in practice
diverged considerably from theory. See
Barry Eichengreen, Globalizing Capital: A History
of the International Monetary System. (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 1996)
produced
two horrific World Wars.
The
reality was that the simple rules of the gold standard imposed on people
economic costs that were literally unbearable. When a nation’s internal price structure diverged
from international price levels, the only legitimate means for that country to
adjust to the drain of gold reserves was by deflation. This meant allowing its economy to contract
until declining wages reduced consumption enough to restore external balance. This implied dramatic declines in wages and
farm income, increases in unemployment, and a sharp rise in business and bank
failures.
It
was not just workers and farmers who found the costs of this type of adjustment
to be high. The business community
itself could not tolerate the resulting uncertainty and instability. Hence, almost as soon as the gold standard
mechanism was in place, entire societies began to collude in trying to offset
its impact. A first recourse was for
countries to increase their use of protective tariffs for both agricultural and
manufactured goods. [xxiv] By
making trade flows less sensitive to price changes, countries could gain some
degree of greater predictability in their international transactions and be
less vulnerable to sudden and unanticipated gold outflows.
A
further expedient was the rush by the major European powers, the United States
and Japan, to establish formal colonies in the last quarter of the nineteenth
century, The
logic of free trade had been strongly anti-colonial, since the costs of empire
would not be offset by corresponding benefits if all traders had access to the
same markets and investment opportunities. But with the rise of protectionism in
international trade, this calculation was reversed. Newly acquired colonies would be protected by
the imperial powers’ tariffs and the colonizers’ traders would have privileged
access to the colonies’ markets and raw materials. The “rush to empire” of this period
intensified the political, military, and economic rivalry between England and
Germany that culminated in the
[xxiv] Peter Gourevitch, Politics in Hard Times: Comparative Responses
to International Economic Crises (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1996), ch 3; Christopher Chase-Dunn, Yiilcio
Kawano, and Benjamin Brewer, “Trade Globalization Since 1795: Waves of Integration
in the World-System” American Sociological Review. 65:1 (February 2000): 77-95.
16
First
World War. [xxv]
For Polanyi, the imperialist impulse cannot be found somewhere
in the genetic code of nations; rather it materializes as nations struggle to
find some way to protect themselves from the relentless pressures of the gold
standard system. The flow of resources
from a lucrative colony might save the nation from a wrenching crisis caused by a sudden outflows of gold, and the exploitation of the
overseas populations might help to keep domestic class relations from becoming
even more explosive.
Polanyi argues that the utopianism of the market liberals
led them to invent the gold standard as a mechanism that would bring a borderless
world of growing prosperity. Instead,
the relentless shocks of the gold standard forced nations to consolidate
themselves around heightened national, and then, imperial boundaries. The gold standard continued to exert disciplinary
pressure on nations, but its functioning was effectively undermined by the rise
of various forms of protectionism, from tariff barriers to empires. And yet even when this whole contradictory
system came crashing down with the first World War,
the gold standard was so taken for granted that statesmen mobilized to restore
it. The whole drama was played out again
tragically in the 1920’s and 1930’s, as nations were forced to choose between
protecting the exchange rate and protecting their citizens. It was out of this stalemate that fascism
emerged. In Polanyi’s
view, the fascist impulse - to protect society from the market by sacrificing
human freedom - was universal, but local contingencies determined where fascist
regimes were successful in taking power.
Polanyi’s arguments are so important for contemporary
debates about globalization because neoliberals
embrace the same utopian vision that inspired the gold standard. Since the end of the Cold War, we have been
[xxv] Polanyi’s argument is quite different from Lenin’s thesis
that intensifying inter-imperialist conflicts are a product of the growth of finance
capital in the final stage of capitalist development. Polanyi takes pains
to argue that financial capitalists can be a major force for preventing war.
constantly
told that the integration of the global economy is making national boundaries
obsolete and is laying the basis for a new era of global peace. Once nations recognize the logic of the global
marketplace and open their economies to free movement of goods and capital,
international conflict will be replaced by benign competition to produce ever
more exciting goods and services. As
with their predecessors, neoliberals insist that all
nations have to do is trust in the effectiveness of self-regulating markets.
To
be sure, the current global financial system is quite different from the gold
standard. Exchange rates and national
currencies are no longer fixed in relation to gold; most currencies are allowed
to fluctuate in value on the foreign exchange markets. There are also powerful international
financial institutions such as the International Monetary Fund and the World
Bank that play a major role in managing the global system. But behind these important differences there
lies a fundamental commonality - the belief that if individuals and firms are
given maximum freedom to pursue their economic self-interest, then the global
marketplace will make everyone better off.
It
is this fundamental belief that lies behind the systematic efforts of neoliberals to dismantle restraints on trade and capital
flows and to reduce governmental “interference” in the organization of economic
life. An influential defender of
globalization writes:
“When your country recognizes... the rules of the free market in
today’s global economy, and decides to abide by them, it puts on what I call
“the Golden Straitjacket.” The Golden
Straitjacket is the defining political-economic garment of this globalization
era. The Cold War had the Mao suit, the
Nehru jacket, the Russian fur. Globalization
has only the Golden Straitjacket. If your
country has not been fitted for one, it will be soon.” [xxvi]
This writer goes onto say
that the Golden Straitjacket requires shrinking the state, removing
restrictions on trade and capital movements, and deregulating capital markets. Moreover, he cheerfully describe
how the constraints of this garment are enforced by the “Electronic Herd” of
international traders on foreign exchange arid financial markets.
Polanyi’s analysis of the three fictitious commodities
teaches us that this neoliberal vision of automatic
[xxvi]
Thomas Friedman, The Lexus and the Olive Tree. (New York: Farrar Strauss, 1999), p. 96.
18
market
adjustment at the global level is a dangerous fantasy. Just as national economies depend on an active
governmental role, so does the global economy need strong regulatory
institutions, including a lender of last resort. Without such institutions, particular
economies - and perhaps the entire global economy - will suffer crippling
economic crises.
But
the more fundamental point that we learn from Polanyi
is that market Liberalism makes demands on ordinary people that are simply not
sustainable. Workers, farmers, and small
business people will not tolerate for any length of time a pattern of economic
organization in which they are subject to periodic, dramatic fluctuations in
their daily economic circumstances. In
short, the neoliberal utopia of a borderless and
peaceful globe requires that millions of ordinary people throughout the world
have the flexibility to tolerate - perhaps as often as every five or ten years -
a prolonged spell in which they must survive on half or less of what they
earned before. Polanyi
believes that to expect that kind of flexibility is both morally wrong arid
deeply unrealistic. To him it is
inevitable that people will mobilize to protect themselves from these economic
shocks.
Moreover,
the recent period of ascendant neoliberalism has
already witnessed widespread protests occurring around the world where people
attempt to resist the economic disruptions of globalization. [xxvii]
As such
dissatisfactions intensify, social order becomes more problematic and the danger
increases that political leaders will seek to divert discontent by scapegoating internal or external enemies. This is how the utopian vision of neoliberals leads not to peace but to intensified conflict.
In many parts of Africa, for example,
the devastating effects of structural adjustment policies have disintegrated
societies and produced famine and civil war. Elsewhere, the post-Cold War period has seen
the emergence of militantly nationalist regimes with aggressive intentions
towards both neighbors and their own ethnic minorities. [xxviii]
Moreover, in every corner of the globe,
[xxvii] John Walton and
David Seddon, Free Markets & Food Riots: The Politics of Global Adjustment.
(Cambridge,
Mass.: Blackwell, 1994).
[xxviii] For an
argument that many recent examples of global turmoil can be traced to the
international economic regime, see Michel Cossudovsky,
The Globalisation of Poverty: Impacts of IMF and
World Bank Reforms. (Penarig,
Malaysia: Third World Network, 1997).
19
militant
movements, often intermixed with religious fundamentalism, are poised to take
advantage of the economic and social shocks of globalization. If Polanyi is right,
these signs of disorder are harbingers of even more dangerous circumstances in
the future.
Though
he wrote The Great Transformation during W.W. II, Polanyi
remained optimistic about the future; he thought the cycle of international
conflict could be broken. The key step
was to overturn the belief that social life should be subordinated to the
market mechanism. Once free of this
“obsolete market mentality,” [xxix] the
path would be open to subordinate both national economies and the global
economy to democratic politics. Polanyi sees Roosevelt’s New Deal as a model of these
future possibilities. Roosevelt’s
reforms mean that the U.S. economy continues to be organized around markets and
market activity, but a new set of regulatory mechanisms makes it possible to
buffer both human beings and nature from the pressures of market forces. [xxx] Through democratic
politics, people decide that the elderly should be protected from the need to
earn income through Social Security. Similarly,
democratic politics expands the rights of working people to form effective
unions through the National Labor Relations Act. Polanyi sees these
initiatives as the start of a process by which society would decide through
democratic means to protect individuals and nature from certain economic
dangers.
At
the global level, Polanyi anticipates an international
economic order with high levels of international
[xxix] This is the
title that Polanyi gave to an important 1947 essay
that is reprinted in George Dalton, ed., Primitive, Archaic, and Modern
Economies.
[xxx] The New Deal
actually did little to protect the environment. Nevertheless, when environmentalists later
gained the political strength to win reforms, agencies such as the
Environmental Protection Agency followed the regulatory model of the New Deal.
20
trade
and cooperation. He does not lay out a
set of blueprints, but he is clear on the principles:
“However, with the disappearance of the automatic mechanism of the gold
standard, governments will find it possible to drop the most obstructive
features of absolute sovereignty, the refusal to collaborate in international
economics. At the same time it will
become possible to tolerate willingly that other nations shape their domestic
institutions according to their inclinations, thus transcending the pernicious
nineteenth century dogma of the necessary uniformity of domestic regimes within
the orbit of world economy.” (253)
In other words,
collaboration among governments would produce a set of agreements to facilitate
high levels of international trade, but societies would have multiple means to
buffer themselves from the pressures of the global economy. Moreover, with an end to the effort to impose
a single economic model, developing nations would have expanded opportunities
to improve the welfare of their people. This
vision also assumes a set of global regulatory structures that would place
limits on the play of market forces. [xxxi]
Polanyi’s vision depends on expanding the role of
government both domestically and internationally. He challenges the now fashionable views that
more government will lead inevitably to both bad economic results and excessive
state control of social life. For him, a
substantial governmental role is indispensable for managing the fictitious
commodities, so there is no reason to take seriously the market liberal axiom
that governments are by definition ineffectual. But he also explicitly refutes the claim that
the expansion of government would necessarily take an oppressive form. He argues instead that:
“The passing of market-economy can become the beginning of an era of unprecedented
freedom. Juridical and actual freedom
can be made wider and more general than ever before; regulation and control can
achieve freedom not only for the few, but for all.” (256)
But
the conception of freedom that he outlines goes beyond a reduction of economic
and social injustice; he also calls for an expansion of civil liberties,
stressing that:
[xxxi] For a recent
effort to concretize this vision, see John Eatwell
and Lance Taylor, Global Finance at Risk: The Case for International
Regulation. New York: New Press, 2000.
“In an established society, the right to nonconformity
must be institutionally protected. The
individual must be free to follow his conscience without fear of the powers
that happen to be entrusted with administrative tasks in some of the fields of
social life.” (255)
He ends the book with
these eloquent words:
“As long as [man] is true to his task of creating more abundant freedom
for all, he need not fear that either power or planning will turn against him
and destroy the freedom he is building by their instrumentality. This is the meaning of freedom in a complex
society; it gives us all the certainty that we need.” (259B) [xxxii]
Of course,
Polanyi’s optimism about the immediate post-World War
II era was not justified by the actual course of events. The coming of the Cold War meant that the New
Deal was the end of reform in the US, not the beginning. Planned global economic cooperation gave way
relatively quickly to new initiatives to expand the global role of markets. To be sure, the considerable achievements of
European social democratic governments, particularly in Scandinavia, from the
1940’s through the 1990’s provides concrete evidence that Polanyi’s
vision was both powerful and realistic. But
in the larger countries, Polanyi’s vision was
orphaned, and the opposing views of market liberals like Hayek steadily gained
strength, triumphing in the 1990s and 1990s.
Yet
now that the Cold War is history, Polanyi’s initial
optimism might finally be vindicated. There
is a real alternative to the familiar scenario in which the unsustainability
of market liberalism produces economic crises and the reemergence of authoritarian
and aggressive regimes. The alternative
is that ordinary people in nations around the globe engage in a common effort
to subordinate the economy to democratic politics and rebuild the global
economy on the basis of international cooperation. Indeed, there were clear signs in the last
years of the 1990s that such a transnational social movement to reshape the
global economy is now more than a theoretical
[xxxii] Polariyi believes that a complex society requires the state
to exercise a monopoly on violence. “Power and compulsion are part of that reality
[of human society]; an ideal that would ban them from society must be invalid.”
(259A).
22
possibility.
[xxxiii] Activists
in both the developed and developing countries have organized militant protests
against the international institutions - the World Trade Organization, the
International Monetary Fund, and the World Bank - that enforce the rules of neoliberalism. Groups
around the world have begun an intense global dialogue over the reconstruction
of the global financial order. [xxxiv]
This
nascent movement faces enormous obstacles; it will not be easy to forge a
durable alliance that reconciles the often conflicting interests of people in
the global South with those in the global North. Moreover, the more successful such a movement
is, the more formidable will be the strategic challenges it faces. It remains highly uncertain whether the global
order can be reformed from below without plunging the world economy into the
kind of crisis that occurs when investors panic. Nevertheless, it is of enormous significance
that for the first time in history, the governance structure of the global
economy has become the central target of transnational social movement
activity.
This
transnational movement is an indication of the continuing vitality and
practicality of Polanyi’s vision. For Polanyi, the
deepest flaw in market liberalism is that it subordinates human purposes to the
logic of an impersonal market mechanism. He argues instead that human beings should use
the instruments of democratic governance to control and direct the economy to
meet our individual and collective needs. Polanyi shows that
the failure to take up this challenge produced enormous suffering in the last
century. His prophecy for the new
century could not be clearer.
[xxxiii] See Peter
Evans, “Fighting Marginalization with Transnational Networks: Counter-Hegemonic
Globalization,” Contemporary Sociology 29:1 (January 2000): 230-241.
[xxxiv] For a North
American perspective on these discussions and a useful guide to additional
resources, see Sarah Anderson and John Cavanaugh (with Thea
Lee), Field Guide to the Global Economy. New York: New Press, 2000.
23