The Competitiveness of Nations in a Global Knowledge-Based Economy
Joe Bain
Industrial
Organization
Conservation
Performance
2nd Edition, John Wiley,1968,
425-427
For any of a group of industries whose operations
involve extraction of natural resources (mining, petroleum production,
agricultural cultivation, lumbering, commercial fisheries) a significant
dimension of the market performance of the firms engaged involves how well they
do in the matter of “conservation” of resources. To paraphrase the popular literature on
this matter, conservation in an economic sense of course does not mean non-use
or simple deferment of use, but “wise use” of the resources being exploited.
In technical terms, good
conservation requires a choice of technique of exploitation, time pattern of
production, and time pattern of investments and other costs, which together
yield an optimal net social benefit relative to costs over all future time
periods in which society is interested. In determining this optimum,
dis
425
tant future benefits and costs should be appropriately
discounted by whatever rate of “time preference” society wishes to assign in
assessing the relative importance of current as opposed to future benefits and
sacrifices. And conservation
performance is poor to the extent that enterprises deviate from this abstract
ideal.
An adequate operational definition of ideal conservation
performance is extremely complex and next to impossible to apply fully in the
evaluation of actual performance. Using the definition just given as a
guide, however, it is possible to identify certain types of gross departure from
good conservation which would have to be censured under any acceptable
criterion. These
include:
1. Exploitation of resources by a technique that raises
both present and future costs above the obtainable minimum while reducing or not
increasing the amount of resources ultimately recovered, or the amount of use
obtained from resources over time.
2. Unduly rapid or intensive current use of resources
which has the result of impairing (or eliminating) future use of the resources
to a degree not compensated by current additions to
output.
3. Pinching on current costs or investments in the use
and development of resources in a way that curtails future use or raises future
costs of use to a disproportionate degree.
What of the actual performance of industries in regard
to conservation? Of course, only a
minor proportion of all industries are sufficiently involved in extraction to
make conservation an issue, and for these we do not have highly organized,
systematic information on which to base an overall appraisal. However, a broad scattering of evidence
on individual cases suggests that, among extractive industries, conservation
performance is or has very frequently been poor.
Thus we observe in petroleum production in the
These deviations from reasonably good conservation
performance seem in large part attributable to four things: (1) antagonistic
exploita-
426
tion of resource deposits by competing interests, in
which a competitive race to capture the resource or its output before others do
results in a disregard of long-run yield considerations; (2) an inherent
“sort-sighted-ness” of firms engaged in exploiting resources - firms that attach
much less importance to distant future production than society would, or than
they do to immediate profits; (3) competitive conditions which bring about such
low returns to firms in some extractive industries that they cannot afford to
invest in the long-run maintenance of resource yields; and (4) stupidity. Whatever the cause, poor market
performance in the matter of conservation has evidently been chargeable against
firms in many extractive industries. It is encouraging, in the light of this,
that in the past twenty or thirty years there has been a rapidly increasing body
of governmental regulations designed to encourage or require better conservation
performance on the part of these industries.
427